scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessBookDOI

Financial Development, Financial Fragility, and Growth

TLDR
In this paper, the authors study the apparent contradiction between two strands of the literature on the effects of financial intermediation on economic activity and find that a positive long-run relationship between financial intermediary and output growth coexists with a mostly negative short run relationship, and further develop an explanation for these contrasting effects by relating them to recent theoretical models.
Abstract
The authors study the apparent contradiction between two strands of the literature on the effects of financial intermediation on economic activity. On the one hand, the empirical growth literature finds a positive effect of financial depth as measured by, for instance, private domestic credit and liquid liabilities (for example, Levine, Loayza, and Beck 2000). On the other hand, the banking and currency crisis literature finds that monetary aggregates, such as domestic credit, are among the best predictors of crises and their related economic downturns (for example, Kaminski and Reinhart 1999). The authors account for these contrasting effects based on the distinction between the short- and long-run impacts of financial intermediation. Working with a panel of cross-country and time-series observations, they estimate an encompassing model of short- and long-run effects using the Pooled Mean Group estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (1999). Their conclusion from this analysis is that a positive long-run relationship between financial intermediation and output growth coexists with a mostly negative short-run relationship. The authors further develop an explanation for these contrasting effects by relating them to recent theoretical models, by linking the estimated short-run effects to measures of financial fragility (namely, banking crises and financial volatility), and by jointly analyzing the effects of financial depth and fragility in classic panel growth regressions.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT, FINANCIAL FRAGILITY,
AND GROWTH
*
*
This paper was written while Loayza and Rancière worked in the research department of the Central
Bank of Chile. Research assistance from Megumi Kubota and Guillermo Vuletin is gratefully
acknowledged. We benefited from comments and advice by J. Benhabib, S. Bond, J. Cummings, F.
Gallego, A. Gaytán, P.O. Gourinchas, O. Jeanne, B. Jovanovic, P. Martin, D. Ray, L. Reichlin, K. Schmidt-
Hebbel, M. Spiegel, A. Rose, A. Tornell, R. Soto, Paul Evans –the journal editor--, two anonymous
referees, and seminar participants at New York University, Stanford University, University of California at
Irvine, the Bank of England, the Central Bank of Chile, the Royal Bank of Sweden, the 2001 CESifo
Summer Institute in Venice, and the 2001 Meetings of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic
Association in Montevideo. The usual disclaimer applies. Correspondence: nloayza@worldbank.org.
Norman Loayza
World Bank
Romain Rancière
CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra
September 2004
Abstract
This paper studies the apparent contradiction between two strands of the literature on the effects
of financial intermediation on economic activity. On the one hand, the empirical growth
literature finds a positive effect of financial depth as measured by, for instance, private domestic
credit and liquid liabilities (e.g., Levine, Loayza, and Beck 2000). On the other hand, the banking
and currency crisis literature finds that monetary aggregates, such as domestic credit, are among
the best predictors of crises and their related economic downturns (e.g., Kaminski and Reinhart
1999). The paper accounts for these contrasting effects based on the distinction between the
short- and long-run impacts of financial intermediation. Working with a panel of cross-country
and time-series observations, the paper estimates an encompassing model of short- and long-run
effects using the Pooled Mean Group estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (1999).
The conclusion from this analysis is that a positive long-run relationship between financial
intermediation and output growth co-exists with a, mostly, negative short-run relationship. The
paper further develops an explanation for these contrasting effects by relating them to recent
theoretical models, by linking the estimated short-run effects to measures of financial fragility
(namely, banking crises and financial volatility), and by jointly analyzing the effects of financial
depth and fragility in classic panel growth regressions.

2
FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT, FINANCIAL FRAGILITY, AND GROWTH
I. INTRODUCTION
This paper analyzes the apparent contradiction between two strands of the
literature on the effects of financial intermediation on economic activity. On the one
hand, the empirical growth literature finds a positive effect of measures of private
domestic credit and liquid liabilities on per capita GDP growth (as illustration, see Figure
1). This is interpreted as the growth enhancing effect of financial development (e.g.,
King and Levine, 1993; Levine, Loayza, and Beck, 2000). On the other hand, the
banking and currency crisis literature finds that monetary aggregates, such as domestic
credit, are among the best predictors for crises (e.g., Demirguc-Kunt and Degatriache,
1998 and 2000; Gourinchas, Landerretche, and Valdés, 1999; Kaminsky and Reinhart,
1999). Since banking crises usually lead to recessions, an expansion of domestic credit
would then be associated to growth slowdowns (see Figure 2).
A similar divide exists at the theoretical level.
1
According to the endogenous
growth literature, financial deepening leads to a more efficient allocation of savings to
productive investment projects (see Greenwood and Jovanovic, 1990; Bencivenga and
Smith, 1991). Conversely, the financial crisis literature points to the destabilizing effect
of financial liberalization as it leads to an unduly large expansion of credit. Overlending
would occur through a combination of channels, including a limited monitoring capacity
of regulatory agencies, the inability of banks to discriminate good projects during
investment booms, and the existence of an explicit or implicit insurance against banking
failures (Schneider and Tornell, 2004; Aghion, Bacchetta and Banerjee, 2003). Not
surprisingly, each strand of the literature has produced its own set of policy implications.
Thus, researchers that emphasize the findings of the endogenous growth literature
advocate financial liberalization and deepening (e.g., Roubini and Sala-i-Martin, 1992),
while those that concentrate on crises caution against “excesive” financial liberalization
(e.g., Balino and Sundarajan, 1991; Gavin and Hausman, 1995).
This paper contributes to the debate on the effects of financial deepening from an
empirical perspective. First, we want to highlight and illustrate the contrasting effects of

3
financial liberalization and credit expansion on economic activity. Second, we attempt to
provide an empirical explanation to these contrasting effects. In particular, on the one
hand we relate the positive influence of financial depth on investment and growth to the
long-run effect of financial liberalization; and, on the other, we describe a link between
the negative impact of financial volatility and crisis and the short-run effect of
liberalization. Although it is not our purpose to test competing theories, our empirical
results provide support to some recent theoretical models predicting that financial
liberalization can both generate short-run instability and higher long-run growth.
The paper is organized as follows. In section II we examine the output growth
effects of cyclical and trend changes of financial intermediation. For this purpose, we
estimate an encompassing model of short- and long-run effects using a panel of cross-
country and time-series observations. Our basic econometric technique is the Pooled
Mean Group estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (1999). By focusing on
effects at different time horizons, we set the basis for an explanation of the apparently
contradictory effects of financial intermediation on economic activity. In section III, we
discuss and develop further this explanation. First, we link our short- and long-run
results to recent theoretical models on the effects of financial liberalization. Second,
since our econometric methodology allows us to estimate country-specific short-run
effects of financial intermediation on output growth, we analyze their relationship with
country-specific measures of financial fragility, namely, banking crises and volatility.
And third, we go back to the classic context of growth regressions and consider whether
the volatility and crises aspects of financial liberalization are relevant growth
determinants, along with the usual measures of financial depth. Section IV concludes.
II. S
HORT- AND LONG-RUN GROWTH EFFECTS OF FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION
In this section we estimate an empirical model that encompasses the short- and
long-run growth effects of financial intermediation. We use the estimation results to
formulate an empirical explanation of the apparently contradictory effects of financial
intermediation on economic activity. This explanation is based on the distinction
1
Except for a few rather recent papers, some of the reviewed below in the paper.

4
between the cycle and trend changes of financial intermediation and their corresponding
effects on output growth.
Instead of averaging the data per country to isolate trend effects, we estimate both
short- and long-run effects using a data-field composed of a relatively large sample of
countries and annual observations. Our method can be summarized as a panel error-
correction model, where short- and long-run effects are estimated jointly from a general
autoregressive distributed-lag (ARDL) model and where short-run effects are allowed to
vary across countries.
We propose this panel error-correction method as an alternative to the traditional
method of time averaging for the following reasons. First, while averaging clearly
induces a loss of information, it is not obvious that averaging over fixed-length intervals
effectively eliminates business-cycle fluctuations. Second, averaging eliminates
information that may be used to estimate a more flexible model that allows for some
parameter heterogeneity across countries. Third, and most importantly for our purposes,
averaging hides the dynamic relationship between financial intermediation and economic
activity, particularly the presence of opposite effects at different time frequencies.
2
A. Methodology
Empirical estimation poses two issues. The first is the need to separate and
estimate short- and long-run effects without the need to decompose directly trend and
transitory components of growth, financial intermediation, and the other explanatory
variables. We treat this issue below in the context of single-country estimation. The
second issue is the likely possibility that the parameters in the relationship between
financial intermediation and economic activity be different across countries. It can be
argued that country heterogeneity is particularly relevant in short-run relationships, given
that countries are affected by overlending and financial crises to widely different degrees.
On the other hand, we can expect that long-run relationships would be more
homogeneous across countries. We discuss below the issue of heterogeneity in the
context of multi-country estimation.
2
Similar arguments are made by Attanasio, Scorcu, and Picci (2000) in their cross-country study on the
dynamic relationship between saving, investment, and growth.

5
Single-country estimation
The challenge we face is to estimate long- and short-run relationships without
observing the long- and short-run components of the variables involved. Over the last
decade or so, a booming cointegration literature has focused on the estimation of long-run
relationships among I(1) variables (Johansen 1995, Phillips and Hansen 1990). From this
literature, two common misconceptions have been derived. The first one is that long-run
relationships exist only in the context of cointegration among integrated variables. The
second one is that standard methods of estimation and inference are incorrect.
A recent literature, represented in Pesaran and Smith (1995), Pesaran (1997) and
Pesaran and Shin (1999), has argued against both misconceptions. These authors show
that simple modifications to standard methods can render consistent and efficient
estimates of the parameters in a long-run relationship between both integrated and
stationary variables and that inference on these parameters can be conducted using
standard tests. Furthermore, these methods avoid the need for pre-testing and order-of-
integration conformability given that they are valid whether the variables of interest are
I(0) or I(1). The main requirements for the validity of this methodology are that, first,
there exist a long-run relationship among the variables of interest and, second, the
dynamic specification of the model be sufficiently augmented so that the regressors are
strictly exogenous and the resulting residual is serially uncorrelated.
3
Pesaran and co-
authors label this the “autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) approach” to long-run
modeling.
In order to comply with the requirements for standard estimation and inference,
we embed a long-run growth regression equation into an ARDL (p, q) model. In error-
correction form, this can be written as follows:
() () ( ) () ( )
{}
[]
it
t
i
ii
t
i
i
q
j
jt
i
i
j
jt
i
p
j
i
j
t
i
XyXyy
εββϕδγ
++++=
=
=
1
10
1
1
0
1
1
(1)
where,
y is the per capita GDP growth rate, X represents a set of growth determinants
including financial depth and control variables,
γ
and
δ
are the short-run coefficients
3
It is worth noting that the assumption of a unique long-run relationship underlies implicitly the various
single-equation based estimators of long-run relationships commonly found in the cointegration literature.
Without such assumption, these estimators would at best identify some linear combination of all the long-
run relationships present in the data.

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Capital Market and Business Cycle Volatility

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigated cross-country evidence on how capital markets affect business cycle volatilities, and found that countries with more developed capital markets have smoother economic fluctuations.
Journal ArticleDOI

Bank credit and economic growth: Short-run evidence from a dynamic threshold panel model

TL;DR: In this article, the authors investigated short run nonlinear impacts of bank credit on economic growth in 17 advanced economies from 1870 to 2013 and found that an inverted U-shaped relationship and credit threshold of 135% was statistically and significantly identified in the post-World War II sample.
Posted Content

Financial development and income inequality in Africa: A panel heterogeneous approach

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigated the relationship between financial development and income inequality in Africa and found that the finance-inequality relationship in the sample of African countries studied is non-linear and ranges from an inverted U-shape to a u-shape depending on the measure of financial development.
Journal ArticleDOI

Macro-economic Factors Influencing Tourism Entrepreneurship: The Case of Kazakhstan:

TL;DR: In emerging economies like Kazakhstan, tourism development needs active entrepreneurship as mentioned in this paper, and tourism development contributes to economic development, as the country emerges from the post-Soviet era, and as such tourism development need active entrepreneurship.
Journal ArticleDOI

Financial Integration and Economic Growth in the COMESA and SADC Regions

TL;DR: In this article, the authors examined the relationship between financial integration and economic growth in the COMESA and SADC regions using panel data methods to examine the relationship of financial integration with economic growth.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations.

TL;DR: In this article, the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator optimally exploits all the linear moment restrictions that follow from the assumption of no serial correlation in the errors, in an equation which contains individual effects, lagged dependent variables and no strictly exogenous variables.
Report SeriesDOI

Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models

TL;DR: In this paper, two alternative linear estimators that are designed to improve the properties of the standard first-differenced GMM estimator are presented. But both estimators require restrictions on the initial conditions process.
Journal ArticleDOI

Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models

TL;DR: In this paper, a framework for efficient IV estimators of random effects models with information in levels which can accommodate predetermined variables is presented. But the authors do not consider models with predetermined variables that have constant correlation with the effects.
ReportDOI

Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries

TL;DR: For 98 countries in the period 1960-1985, the growth rate of real per capita GDP is positively related to initial human capital (proxied by 1960 school-enrollment rates) and negatively related to the initial (1960) level as mentioned in this paper.
Journal ArticleDOI

Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examined a cross-section of about 80 countries for the period 1960-89 and found that various measures of financial development are strongly associated with both current and later rates of economic growth.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (11)
Q1. What are the contributions in "Financial development, financial fragility," ?

This paper studies the apparent contradiction between two strands of the literature on the effects of financial intermediation on economic activity. The paper accounts for these contrasting effects based on the distinction between the shortand long-run impacts of financial intermediation. Working with a panel of cross-country and time-series observations, the paper estimates an encompassing model of shortand long-run effects using the Pooled Mean Group estimator developed by Pesaran, Shin, and Smith ( 1999 ). The paper further develops an explanation for these contrasting effects by relating them to recent theoretical models, by linking the estimated short-run effects to measures of financial fragility ( namely, banking crises and financial volatility ), and by jointly analyzing the effects of financial depth and fragility in classic panel growth regressions. 

Recognizing the possibility of a dual effect of financial intermediation on economic growth, this paper estimates an encompassing empirical model of long- and short-run effects using a sample of cross-country and time-series observations. The authors find that a positive long-run relationship between financial intermediation and output growth can coexist with a negative short-run relationship, which indeed is the case for the average country in the sample. Since the methodology allows us to obtain the short-run effects of financial intermediation on growth country by country, the authors can attempt to link these effects to the aspects of financial liberalization that the literature proposes as harmful to growth. The authors find that financially fragile countries, namely those that experience banking crises or suffer high financial volatility, tend to present significantly negative short-run effects of intermediation on growth. 

The main requirements for the validity of this methodology are that, first, there exist a long-run relationship among the variables of interest and, second, the dynamic specification of the model be sufficiently augmented so that the regressors are strictly exogenous and the resulting residual is serially uncorrelated. 

whereas financial depth leads to higher growth, financial fragility --as captured by financial volatility and banking crises-- has negative growth consequences. 

The first are that the regression residuals be serially uncorrelated and that the explanatory variables can be treated as exogenous. 

When the main interest is on the long-run parameters, the lag order of the ARDL can be selected using some consistent information criteria (such as the Schwartz-Bayesian Criterion) on a country-by-country basis. 

The Hausman test does not reject the joint homogeneity of all long-run parameters; and it does not reject the homogeneity of individual long-run coefficients except for that on initial income. 

The authors can get a broad sense of the economic importance of these effects by using the point estimate of the regression coefficients to calculate the growth impact of a change in their financial measures. 

the estimation of the long-run slope coefficients is done jointly across countries through a (concentrated) maximum likelihood procedure. 

On the other hand, an increase in one sample standard deviation of financial depth leads to economic growth rising by 0.9 percentage points. 

Countries that experienced financial crises in the last 40 years exhibit an average shortrun impact of financial intermediation on output growth that is significantly more negative than the average of countries that did not have any crisis.