scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of Time Over Five Decades

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the authors use five decades of time-use surveys to document trends in the allocation of time and find that a dramatic increase in leisure time lies behind the relatively stable number of market hours worked (per working-age adult) between 1965 and 2003.

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
MEASURING TRENDS IN LEISURE: THE
ALLOCATION OF TIME OVER FIVE DECADES
Mark Aguiar
Erik Hurst
Working Paper 12082
http://www.nber.org/papers/w12082
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
March 2006
We thank Susanto Basu, Gary Becker, Kathy Bradbury, Kerwin Charles, Raj Chetty, Steve Davis, Jordi Galí,
Rueben Gronau, Dan Hamermesh, Chad Jones, Ellen McGrattan, Bruce Mayer, Kevin Murphy, Derek Neal,
Valerie Ramey, Richard Rogerson, Frank Stafford, and seminar participants at the Minneapolis Federal
Reserve, the Cleveland Federal Reserve (NBER EFG/RSW meeting), the University of Rochester, the
University of Wisconsin’s Institute for Poverty Research Summer Institute, NBER Summer Institute in Labor
Studies, the University of California at San Diego, the University of California at Berkeley, the University
of Chicago, Columbia University, Boston College, Harvard, Wharton, and the University of Maryland. We
thank Dan Reichgott for research assistance. Hurst would like to acknowledge the financial support of the
University of Chicago’s Graduate School of Business. The views expressed in this paper are solely those
of the authors and do not reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston or the Federal
Reserve System. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
©2006 by Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two
paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given
to the source.

Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of Time Over Five Decades
Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst
NBER Working Paper No. 12082
March 2006
JEL No. D12, D13, J22
ABSTRACT
In this paper, we use five decades of time-use surveys to document trends in the allocation of time.
We find that a dramatic increase in leisure time lies behind the relatively stable number of market
hours worked (per working-age adult) between 1965 and 2003. Specifically, we show that leisure
for men increased by 6-8 hours per week (driven by a decline in market work hours) and for women
by 4-8 hours per week (driven by a decline in home production work hours). This increase in leisure
corresponds to roughly an additional 5 to 10 weeks of vacation per year, assuming a 40-hour work
week. Alternatively, the "consumption equivalent" of the increase in leisure is valued at 8 to 9
percent of total 2003 U.S. consumption expenditures. We also find that leisure increased during the
last 40 years for a number of sub-samples of the population, with less-educated adults experiencing
the largest increases. Lastly, we document a growing "inequality" in leisure that is the mirror image
of the growing inequality of wages and expenditures, making welfare calculation based solely on the
latter series incomplete.
Mark Aguiar
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
600 Atlantic Avenue
Boston, MA 02210
mark.aguiar@bos.frb.org
Erik Hurst
Graduate School of Business
University of Chicago
Hyde Park Center
Chicago, IL 60637
and NBER
erik.hurst@gsb.uchicago.edu

2
1. Introduction
In this paper, we document trends in the allocation of time over the last 40 years. In
particular, we focus our attention on measuring how leisure time has evolved within the United
States. In commonly used household surveys designed to measure labor market activity (such as
the Current Population Survey (CPS) and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)), the only
category of time use that is consistently measured is market work hours.
1
As a result, leisure is
almost universally defined as time spent away from market work. However, as noted by Becker
(1965), households can also allocate time towards production outside the formal market sector.
To the extent that non-market (home) production is important and changing over time, leisure
time will be poorly proxied by time spent away from market work. By linking five decades of
detailed time-use surveys, we are able empirically to draw the distinction between leisure and the
complement of market work. In doing so, we document a set of facts about how home production
and leisure have evolved for men and women of differing work status, marital status, and
educational attainment during the last 40 years.
The main empirical finding in this paper is that leisure time—measured in a variety of
ways—has increased significantly in the United States between 1965 and 2003.
2
When
computing our measures of leisure, we separate out other uses of household time, including time
spent in market work, time spent in non-market (home) production, time spent obtaining human
capital, and time spent in heath care. Given that some categories of time use are easier to
categorize as leisure than others, we create four distinct measures of leisure. Our measures range
from the narrow, which includes activities designed to yield direct utility, such as entertainment,
socializing, active recreation, and general relaxation, to the broad, namely, time spent neither in
1
In some years, the PSID asks respondents to individually report the amount of time they spent on household chores
during a given week. These data are exploited by Roberts and Rupert (1995) to document a decline in total work,
which, for the overlapping periods, is consistent with the trends documented in this paper.
2
We provide a formal definition of leisure in Section 3.

3
market production nor in non-market production. While the magnitudes differ slightly, the
conclusions drawn are similar across each of the leisure measures.
Using our preferred definition of leisure, we find that leisure has increased by 7.9 hours
per week on average for men and by 6.0 hours for women between 1965 and 2003, controlling for
demographics. Interestingly, the decline in total work (the sum of total market work and total
non-market work) was nearly identical for the men and women (7.9 and 7.7 hours per week,
respectively). These increases in leisure are extremely large. In 1965, the average man spent 61
hours per week and the average women spent 54 hours per week in total market and non-market
work. The increase in weekly leisure we document between 1965 and 2003 represents 11 to 13
percent of the average total work week in 1965. Valuing time at 2003 market wages, the increase
in leisure has a market value of $5,000 to $5,500 per adult in annual terms. Aggregating over the
adult population, this represents 8 to 9 percent of total GDP in 2003. If we assume the after-tax
market wage represents the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure, to a
first order approximation the increase in leisure is equivalent to 8 to 9 percent of 2003
consumption expenditures.
The adjustments that allow for greater leisure while satisfying the time budget constraint
differ between men and women. Men increased their leisure by allocating less time to the market
sector, whereas leisure time for women increased simultaneously with time spent in market labor.
This increased leisure for women was made possible by a decline in the time women allocated to
home production of roughly 11 hours per week between 1965 and 2003. This more than offset
women’s 5-hours-per-week increase in market labor.
3
We also analyze changes in leisure by educational attainment. We find that men and
women with more than a high school education and men and women with a high school education
or less all increased leisure time between 1965 and 2003. However, while the level of leisure in
3
The magnitudes we present in the introduction correspond to changes in time use conditional on demographic
changes, as shown in Figures 2–5.

4
1965 was roughly equal across educational status, the subsequent increase in leisure was greatest
among less-educated adults. Similarly, we document that the cross-sectional distribution of
leisure time has fanned out over the last 40 years. Given that the least-educated households
experienced the largest gains in leisure, this growing “inequality” in leisure is the mirror image of
the well-documented trends in income and expenditure inequality. The fact that the least-educated
experience the most leisure poses an empirical puzzle for the standard model that relies solely on
income and substitution effects: The time-series evidence suggests that rising incomes induce
greater leisure, while the recent cross-sections suggest that higher incomes are associated with
lower levels of leisure.
2. Related Literature
Three classic book-length references on the allocation of time are Ghez and Becker
(1975), Juster and Stafford (1985), and Robinson and Godbey (1999). The latter is most closely
related to our study. It uses the same time-use surveys we use from 1965, 1975, and 1985, as well
as some additional time-use information from the early 1990s.
4
Our paper adds to the earlier
results of Juster and Stafford and Robinson and Godbey by documenting the growing dispersion
in leisure as well as analyzing a longer time series. We also consider alternative leisure
aggregates. Several other studies have explored the trends in housework, including Bianchi et al.
(2000) and Roberts and Rupert (1995). In addition to extending the sample of Robinson and
Godbey through the late 1990s, the former work contains a nice summary of the existing
sociology literature on housework. The latter uses the market work and housework measures in
the PSID, as does Knowles (2005), who focuses on relative work hours (at home and in the
market) of spouses in younger households. For a popular but controversial study that draws
4
Juster and Stafford (1985) fully examined unconditional and conditional time use in the United States using the 1965
and 1975 time diaries. In the first edition of their book (1997), Robinson and Godbey extended the analysis of Juster
and Stafford by examining the trends in time use across 1965, 1975, and 1985. In their second edition, Robinson and
Godbey added a short chapter entitled “A 1990s Update: Trends Since 1985”. In that chapter, they briefly discuss how
unconditional measures of time in the early 1990s compare with unconditional measures of time use from earlier
decades. However, their discussion does not include the conditional time-use analysis that is done in this paper.

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The Economic Importance of Financial Literacy: Theory and Evidence

TL;DR: An assessment of a rapidly growing body of economic research on financial literacy and thoughts on what remains to be learned if researchers are to better inform theoretical and empirical models as well as public policy are offered.
Posted Content

Parental Education and Parental Time with Children

TL;DR: In this article, a cross-sectional analysis of the American Time Use Surveys (ATUS) showed that time spent with children does not follow patterns typical of leisure or home production, suggesting an important difference.
Book ChapterDOI

New Perspectives on Gender

TL;DR: For instance, this paper reviewed the research that has tried to quantify the relevance of these factors in explaining gender differences in labor market outcomes outside of the laboratory setting and described the relationship between social and gender identity norms and women’s labor market choices and outcomes.
Journal ArticleDOI

Gender Identity and Relative Income within Households

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors argue that gender identity norms induce an aversion to a situation where the wife earns more than her husband, and they present evidence that this aversion also impacts marriage formation, the wife's labor force participation, the spouse's income conditional on working, marriage satisfaction, likelihood of divorce, and the division of home production.
Journal ArticleDOI

Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of Time Over Five Decades

TL;DR: The authors used five decades of time-use surveys to document trends in the allocation of time within the United States and found that a dramatic increase in leisure time lies behind the relatively stable number of market hours worked between 1965 and 2003.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Changes in Relative Wages, 1963–1987: Supply and Demand Factors

TL;DR: A simple supply and demand framework is used to analyze changes in the U.S. wage structure from 1963 to 1987 as discussed by the authors, showing that rapid secular growth in the demand for more-educated workers, "more-skilled" workers, and females appears to be the driving force behind observed changes in wage structure.
Journal ArticleDOI

Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill

TL;DR: This paper found that the trend toward increased wage inequality is apparent within narrowly defined education and labor market experience groups, and that much of the increase in wage inequality for males over the last 20 years is due to increased returns to the components of skill other than years of schooling and years of labor market experiences.
Book ChapterDOI

Changes in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a framework for understanding changes in the wage structure and overall earnings inequality, emphasizing the role of supply and demand factors and the interaction of market forces and labor market institutions.
Journal ArticleDOI

Production, growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present the neoclassical model of capital accumulation augmented by choice of labor supply as the basic framework of modern real business cycle analysis and explore the implications of the basic model for perfect foresight capital accumulation and for economic fluctuations initiated by impulses to technology.
Frequently Asked Questions (9)
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "Nber working paper series measuring trends in leisure: the allocation of time over five decades" ?

In this paper, the authors use five decades of time-use surveys to document trends in the allocation of time. Specifically, the authors show that leisure for men increased by 6-8 hours per week ( driven by a decline in market work hours ) and for women by 4-8 hours per week ( driven by a decline in home production work hours ). This increase in leisure corresponds to roughly an additional 5 to 10 weeks of vacation per year, assuming a 40-hour work week. 

This latter calculation acknowledges the possibility that within education and sex categories, the lowest productivity agents remain out of the labor force. 22 Simply multiplying the wage by the average increase in leisure 3 of 6. 9 hours ( Figure 4a ) suggests a market value of increased leisure ranging from $ 5,900 to $ 6,500 per individual on an annual basis. This calculation suggests the market value of the increased leisure ranges from $ 5,000 to $ 5,500 per year ( in 2003 dollars ). On the one hand, they may be overstating the market value by using market wages ( observed or imputed ) to value non-market time. 

In commonly used household surveys designed to measure labor market activity (such as the Current Population Survey (CPS) and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)), the only category of time use that is consistently measured is market work hours. 

the steady decline in home production time over the last 40 years argues for a high elasticity of substitution between time and goods in home production, constant technological improvement in home production, or a combination of the two. 

The result is that the combined pet care and gardening category increases roughly 30 minutes per week between 1965 and 1993, and then increases a little more than one hour per week between 1993 and 2003. 

In this case, the high elasticity between market goods and “home production” time generate a positive elasticity of labor supply. 

The table indicates that married men experienced an unconditional increase in leisure of 4.5 to 5 hours per week during the last 40 years, driven by a 9 hour decrease in market work offset by a 4.7-hour increase in non-market work. 

That is, women transiting into the labor force may be experiencing declines in leisure while their continuously employed or continuously nonemployed counterparts are experiencing large increases in leisure. 

The above calculation used the assumed equality between wages and the marginalproduct of labor to provide a first order approximation to the value of leisure in terms of output.