scispace - formally typeset
Journal ArticleDOI

Pretrial Negotiation, Litigation, and Procedural Rules

Jiong Gong, +1 more
- 01 Apr 2000 - 
- Vol. 38, Iss: 2, pp 218-238
TLDR
In this article, the authors study the effect of fee shifting on the fairness and expenditure of a civil dispute resolution process in the U.S. and find that the English rule shifts the settlement away from the interim fair and unbiased settlement in most circumstances.
Abstract
R. PRESTON MCAFEE [*] We model the civil dispute resolution process as a two-stage game with the parties bargaining to reach a settlement in the first stage and then playing a litigation expenditure game at trial in the second stage. We find that the English rule shifts the settlement away from the interim fair and unbiased settlement in most circumstances. Overall welfare changes are in favor of the party who makes the offer in the pretrial negotiation stage. Lawyers however, always benefit from the English rule, because fee shifting increases the stake of the trial and thus intensifies the use of the legal service. (JEL K40) I. INTRODUCTION Newt Gingrich, in the Contract with America [1994, 145], calls for "common sense legal reforms," including a "so-called loser-pays rule" (in which the unsuccessful party in a suit pays the attorneys' fees of the prevailing party). The "loser-pays rule" (hereafter fee-shifting or English rule), Gingrich argues, "strongly discourages the filing of weak cases as well as encourages the pursuit of strong cases, since claimants can get their court costs reimbursed if they win" [1994, 1461. A voluminous literature, discussed below, supports Gingrich's view. However, by and large, this literature neglects two important considerations in analyzing the English rule. First, the English rule increases the stake of the litigating parties. Thus, although a switch to the English rule may reduce the number of lawsuits, the lawsuits that get to court should involve higher legal expenses. Consequently, the overall effect on legal expenses is unclear. Second, the literature neglects the fairness of the outcome. Do plaintiffs obtain an award justified by the evidence? We provide some theoretical evidence that the English rule distorts outcomes away from a fair outcome. The judicial procedural systems in most nations follow the English rule, which allows for some degree of fee shifting, or the rewarding of legal fees to the winner of legal battles. [1] It is an old British doctrine of "the costs follow the event." The United States is a remarkable exception. [2] The American rule developed gradually. In the early days of the colonies, the procedural system inherited the English rule, allowing attorneys to recover fees from the losing party. Gradually, attorneys found it more lucrative to sign private contingency agreements with their clients and paid less attention to redemption from the losing party. The court in the meantime gradually relaxed enforcement of fee shifting and ceased monitoring legal costs, until the American rule became part of the statutory law. [3] We develop a model that permits us to address the question of the effects of fee shifting on fairness and expenditure at trial. Since pretrial settlement occurs in a significant portion of legal disputes, pretrial negotiation appears empirically important. In environments with symmetrically informed contestants, costly trials will be avoided by settling, because there are no deviating views as to the outcome of the trial. However many disputes do go to trial. Thus, incomplete information also appears to be empirically significant. We allow for incomplete information about the fundamental facts of the case as well as the costs of prevailing at trial. The actual likelihood of prevailing at trial is itself endogenous. We also endogenize expenditure at trial, which is obviously necessary to answer any question about the effects of fee shifting on legal expenditures. Orley Ashenfelter and David Bloom [1993] provided empirical evidence that legal expenditures have a prisoner's dilemma nature, thus appearing to be socially wasteful. Since fee shifting works like a subsidy to winning and a tax on losing, one might reasonably expect fee shifting to increase the stake of the trial and thus to encourage greater legal expenditures, than under the U.S. system. We model a trial as a dispute over a fixed amount of money. …

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Citations
More filters
Posted Content

Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction-Theoretic Approach

TL;DR: In this article, a simple auction-theoretic framework is used to examine symmetric litigation environments where the legal ownership of a disputed asset is unknown to the court, and the court observes only the quality of the case presented by each party, and awards the asset to the party presenting the best case.
Journal ArticleDOI

Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction‐Theoretic Approach*

TL;DR: In this article, a simple auction-theoretic framework is used to examine symmetric litigation environments where the legal ownership of a disputed asset is unknown to the court, and the court observes only the quality of the case presented by each party, and awards the asset to the party presenting the best case.
Journal ArticleDOI

Evidence disclosure and verifiability

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors explore the notion of verifiability by analyzing a simple model of evidence production in contractual relationships with complete information and provide results on maximal and minimal evidence production that are, respectively, necessary and sufficient for implementation.
Journal ArticleDOI

Evidence Disclosure and Verifiability

TL;DR: In this article, the authors explore the conceptual basis of verifiability by explicitly modeling the process of evidence production in contractual relationships of complete information and study how the contracting parties' incentives to disclose evidence (in the form of documents) narrows the set of enforceable contracts and affects what can be considered verifiable.
Journal ArticleDOI

Discovery and Disclosure with Asymmetric Information and Endogenous Expenditure at Trial

TL;DR: In this article, the authors developed a model with asymmetric information, in which the uninformed party makes the offer and when the parties proceed to trial, their endogenous expenditures partially determine the outcome.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model

Ariel Rubinstein
- 01 Jan 1982 - 
TL;DR: In this paper, a study which examined perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model was presented, focusing on a strategic approach adopted for the study and details of the bargaining situation used; discussion on perfect equilibrium.
Book

Bargaining and Markets

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a model of Decentralized Bargaining with one-time entry in a market with one time entry, based on Nash's Solution and Alternating Offers.
Journal ArticleDOI

Equilibrium Selection in Signaling Games

Jeffrey S. Banks, +1 more
- 01 May 1987 - 
TL;DR: In this paper, a new solution concept called divine equilibrium is introduced, which refines the set of sequential equilibria by requiring that off-the-equilibrium-path beliefs satisfy an additional restriction.
Journal ArticleDOI

Litigation and Settlement under Imperfect Information

TL;DR: In this paper, a model of parties' litigation and settlement decisions under imperfect information is studied, and the model shows how informational asymmetry influences parties' decisions, and how it might lead to parties' failure to settle.
Posted Content

Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and Their Resolution

TL;DR: In the early 1970s, economics was relegated by lawyers to the technical role of providing expert advice on a relatively narrow set of laws in such fields as antitrust and labor as mentioned in this paper.