scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Global Imbalances Revisited: The Transfer Problem and Transport Costs in Monopolistic Competition

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the welfare effects of trade imbalances in a two-sector model of monop- olistic competition were studied. And they showed that trade surplus may lead to an appreciation of the exchange rate, to a terms-of-trade improvement and to a welfare increase under standard parameter con- gurations.
About
This article is published in Journal of International Economics.The article was published on 2017-09-01 and is currently open access. It has received 18 citations till now. The article focuses on the topics: Gains from trade & Monopolistic competition.

read more

Citations
More filters
Journal Article

National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade

TL;DR: In this article, the authors focused on differentiated producer goods and constructed a model yielding international returns to scale, and employed this model to explore the relations between international returns, the traditional national return to scale and the factor endowments theory of international trade.
Posted Content

Global Rebalancing with Gravity: Measuring the Burden of Adjustment

TL;DR: In this article, the authors use a forty-two country model of production and trade to assess the implications of eliminating current account imbalances for relative wages, relative GDP's, real wages, and real absorption.
Journal ArticleDOI

Beyond Competitive Devaluations: The Monetary Dimensions of Comparative Advantage

TL;DR: The authors developed a two-country New-Keynesian model allowing for two tradable sectors in each country: while one sector is perfectly competitive, firms in the other sector produce differentiated goods under monopolistic competition subject to sunk entry costs and nominal rigidities, hence their performance is more sensitive to macroeconomic uncertainty.
ReportDOI

The Macroeconomic Stabilization of Tariff Shocks: What is the Optimal Monetary Response?

TL;DR: The authors studied the optimal monetary stabilization of tariff shocks using a New Keynesian model enriched with elements from the trade literature, including global value chains in production, firm dynamics, and comparative advantage between traded sectors.
Posted Content

The optimal use of government purchases for macroeconomic stabilization

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors extend Samuelson's theory of optimal government purchases by considering the contribution of government purchases to macroeconomic stabilization and derive a sufficientstatistics formula for optimal US government purchases.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity

TL;DR: In this article, Pettengill tests whether there is an excessive number of firms in a monopolistically competitive equilibrium by a device of considerable expository merit, and redistributes the resources thus released equally over the remaining firms in the sector, to see if welfare can be improved.
Posted Content

Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a simple formal analysis which incorporates these elements, and show how it can be used to shed some light on some issues which cannot be handled in more conventional models.
Journal ArticleDOI

Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade

TL;DR: The authors developed a simple, general equilibrium model of non-comparative advantage trade and showed that trade and gains from trade will occur, even between countries with identical tastes, technology, and factor endowments.
Book

The Spatial Economy

Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (17)
Q1. What are the contributions in "Global imbalances revisited: the transfer problem and transport costs in monopolistic competition∗" ?

The authors study the welfare effects of trade imbalances in a two-sector model of monopolistic competition. These results can explain why the manufacturing sector may agglomerate in countries that resist the real appreciation of their currency and suggest that a fixed exchange rate and nominal rigidities may generate short-run instability. 

20 A careful empirical investigation of these mechanisms is still missing and seems an important challenge for future research in international finance and trade. 

Its main lesson is that a trade surplus is unambiguously welfare reducing because it involves a double burden, i.e., an income transfer to the trading partner and a terms-of-trade deterioration. 

the dominant approach in the literature on trade imbalances builds on the assumptions of perfectly competitive markets and constant returns to scale. 

Recall that TR = 1 in the absence of price effects, and that an increase in (a depreciation of Home’s exchange rate) also corresponds to a reduction in Home’s relative wage. 

The closest paper to ours is Corsetti, Martin and Pesenti (2013), who develop a twocountry model of monopolistic competition to study how the entry margin affects the price effects of a transfer. 

recall that total expenditure on manufacturing goods equals Ei = 1 + µnipi, which can the authors rewritten using (23) asEi = 1 + µ1− µwiλi. (24)The remaining equilibrium conditions needed to track the relationship between wi and λi are, first, the expression for the price index:P 1−σh (1− µ) = λhw 1−σ(1−µ) h P −σµ h + φ 1−σλfw 1−σ(1−µ) f P −σµ f , (25)in which ni and pi have been substituted out; and, second, the market clearing condition for a firm:1 = qh = (w 1−µ h P µ h ) −σ [ P σ−1h Eh + φ σP σ−1f Ef ] . (26)Given and λi, these equations can be solved for Pi, Ei and wh. 

As in that paper, by linearizing the system of equations in the symmetric equilibrium the authors can obtain an analytical expression for dwh/dλh. 

These are realistic features: the differentiated sector stands for manufacturing production, which is far more traded than services, and trade is not balanced in general. 

As usual, demand for a given good is increasing in the price index Pi and decreasing in its own price, with an elasticity equal to σ. 

Despite their prevalence, the welfare implications of these imbalances are not fully understood, because trade models typically focus on the assumption of balanced trade, while models of international finance often focus on inter-temporal rather intra-temporal trade. 

This is because the model features a production-delocation effect, in that a trade surplus requires a reallocation of labor towards tradeables. 

The ideal price index associated with Ci(M) is:Pi = (∫ n 0 p̃i(z) 1−σdz ) 1 1−σ , (2)where p̃i(z) is the local-currency final price of variety z, gross of any trade cost. 

This result, that a devaluation lowers the price index due to the change in the number of firms, is similar to the production-delocation effect first noticed by Venables (1987) in the context of an iceberg import tariff. 

the real cost of the transfer relative to a model with no price index effect, denoted by TR, isTR ≡ ∆Vh ∆Ṽh = 1− Lh Th(σ − 1) ln ( 1− φ+Nφ−Nφ σ0 1− φ+Nφ−Nφ σT ) . 

given the lower manufacturing share in this scenario, the change in the number of Home firms is now larger and as a result, the price index effect can still lower significantly the cost of the transfer, to 92%/35% of its value. 

As the authors show in the next Section, in the presence of traded intermediates, agglomeration of industrial production is not just beneficial for consumers, it also improves the competitiveness of Chinese firms.