scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Price Indexes, Inequality, and the Measurement of World Poverty

Angus Deaton
- 01 Mar 2010 - 
- Vol. 100, Iss: 1, pp 5-34
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the authors discuss the measurement of world poverty and inequality, with particular attention to the role of purchasing power parity (PPP) price indexes from the International Comparison Project.
Abstract
I discuss the measurement of world poverty and inequality, with particular attention to the role of purchasing power parity (PPP) price indexes from the International Comparison Project. Global inequality increased with the latest revision of the ICP, and this reduced the global poverty line relative to the US dollar. The recent large increase of nearly half a billion poor people came from an inappropriate updating of the global poverty line, not from the ICP revisions. Even so, PPP comparisons between widely different countries rest on weak theoretical and empirical foundations. I argue for wider use of self-reports from international monitoring surveys, and for a global poverty line that is truly denominated in US dollars.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Price indexes, inequality, and the measurement of world poverty
Angus Deaton, Princeton University
January 10
th
, 2010
ABSTRACT
I discuss the statistical basis for measures of world poverty and inequality, with particular
attention to the role of purchasing power parity price indexes from the International
Comparison Project. Global inequality increased sharply with the latest revision of the ICP,
but the recent large increase in global poverty came from an inappropriate updating of the
global line, not from the ICP revision. ICP comparisons between widely different countries
rest on weak empirical and theoretical foundations. I argue for greater use of self-reports in
international monitoring surveys, and for a global poverty line that is denominated in US
dollars.
Presidential Address, American Economic Association, Atlanta, January 2010. I am grateful
to Olivier Dupriez, Alan Heston and Sam Schulhofer-Wohl who have collaborated with me
on related work, to them and to Erwin Diewert, Yuri Dikhanov, D. S. Prasada-Rao, and Fred
Vogel who have over the years taught me about international price comparisons, as well as
the Development Economics Data Group at the World Bank for supplying me with data and
for their patience and help with my questions. I also thank Tony Atkinson, Tim Besley,
Branko Milanovic, François Bourguignon, Anne Case, Olivier Dupriez, Bill Easterly, Alan
Heston and Martin Ravallion for comments on partial drafts. The views expressed here are my
own.

1
This lecture is about counting the number of poor people in the world. If we ask people
whether they consider themselves to be poor, or how much money someone would need to get
by in their community, they appear to have little difficulty in replying. Beyond the local level,
many countries, including the United States, regularly publish national counts of the number
of people in poverty, and while these numbers and the procedures for calculating them are
contested and debated, the estimates typically carry sufficient legitimacy to support policy,
see Connie Citro and Robert Michael (1995) for the history in the US, and Rebecca Blank and
Mark Greenburg (2008) for a recent proposal for reform. But once we try to calculate the
number of poor people in the world, matters are more complicated. The World Bank’s global
poverty count, which started with Montek Ahluwalia, Nicholas Carter and Hollis Chenery
(1979), and which became the dollar-a-day count in the World Development Report 1990, was
incorporated into international policymaking and discussion via the Millennium Development
Goals (MDGs)—the first of which is to “halve, between 1990 and 2015, the proportion of
people whose income is less than $1 a day.” This global count has an apparent transparency
that helps account for its rhetorical success: it is simply the number of people in the world
who live on less than a dollar a day, with the relevant dollar adjusted for international
differences in prices. But this transparency and simplicity is more apparent than real. There
are many complexities beneath the surface, and these are the subject matter of this paper,
particularly the calculation of the global line and the adjustment for international differences
in prices using purchasing power parity exchange rates. Price adjustment is also important for
other purposes, such as the construction of databases such as the Penn World Table, which
underpins almost all of economists’ empirical understanding of the process of economic

2
growth, as well as for the measurement of global income inequality, which is another of my
main concerns here.
One goal of this paper is to understand why almost half a billion people were moved into
poverty at the time of the revision of the purchasing power parity exchange rates in the 2005
round of the International Comparison Project (ICP). This same revision also increased global
income inequality, widening the apparent distance between poor and rich countries. I shall
argue that the increase in poverty had little to do with the ICP, and much to do with an
inappropriate increase in the global poverty line. The causes of the increase in inequality are
harder to pinpoint, but my investigations lead to skepticism about our ability to make precise
comparisons of living standards between widely different countries, for example between
poor countries in Africa and rich countries in the OECD.
In spite of the attention that they receive, global poverty and inequality measures are
arguably of limited interest. Within nations, the procedures for calculating poverty are
routinely debated by the public, the press, legislators, academics, and expert committees, and
this democratic discussion legitimizes the use of the counts in support of programs of
transfers and redistribution. Between nations where there is no supranational authority,
poverty counts have no direct redistributive role, and there is little democratic debate by
citizens, with discussion largely left to international organizations such as the United Nations
and the World Bank, and to non-governmental organizations that focus on international
poverty. These organizations regularly use the global counts as arguments for foreign aid and
for their own activities, and the data have often been effective in mobilizing giving for
poverty alleviation. They may also influence the global strategy of the World Bank,
emphasizing some regions or countries as the expense of others. It is less clear that the counts

3
have any direct relevance for those included in them, given that national policymaking and the
country operations of the World Bank depend on local, not global poverty measures. Global
poverty and global inequality measures have a central place in a cosmopolitan vision of the
world, in which international organizations such as the UN and the World Bank are somehow
supposed to fulfill the redistributive role of the missing global government, see for example
Thomas Pogge (2002) or Peter Singer (2002). For those who do not accept the cosmopolitan
vision as morally compelling or descriptively accurate, such measures are less relevant, John
Rawls (1999), Thomas Nagel (2005), Leif Wenar (2006).
The paper is organized as follows. Section I explains how the dollar a day poverty
numbers are calculated and how they depend on purchasing power parity exchange rates. It
shows that poverty measures are sensitive to the PPPs used in their construction, and
establishes the basic facts and puzzles to be addressed, particularly the increases in poverty
and inequality associated with the latest ICP revisions. Sections II and III are more technical
and can be skipped without losing the thread of the main argument. Section II discusses the
components of the construction of PPPs that are particularly important for measuring world
poverty and inequality, while Section III discusses how PPP indexes need to be reweighted
for use in poverty measurement. It argues, by reference to my related work with Olivier
Dupriez (2009), that the reweighting, although a clear conceptual improvement, matters less
than might be thought. Section IV returns to the main argument and is concerned with the
definition of the global poverty line, and I discuss ways of constructing the line based on the
international price indexes and the national poverty lines of poor countries. As is always the
case with poverty lines, how the poverty line is updated with respect to new information
deserves as much or more attention than how its original value is set. I argue that the updating

4
procedure in current use is incorrect, that it can result in reductions in national poverty
causing increases in global poverty, and that this explains why the global poverty counts
increased so much in the latest revision. Paradoxically, one of the main reasons that India (and
the rest of the world) became poorer was because India had grown too rich. I argue for a
definition of the line, and an updating method, that is substantially different from those
currently in use, and that preserves a better continuity with previous estimates.
Section V, which is again somewhat more technical, is an enquiry into the international
price indexes themselves, with a focus on the factors that affect global inequality. It starts
from the question of how to price comparable goods in different countries and whether the
ever more precise specification of goods by the ICP has had the effect of making poor
countries poorer relative to rich countries, widening our estimates of international inequality,
and causing the global poverty line to increase in dollar terms at a rate that is markedly slower
than the rate of inflation in the US. More generally, I discuss the special difficulties of making
comparisons between countries whose relative prices and patterns of consumption are very
different, for example between Japan and Kenya, or Britain and Cameroon. Such comparisons
are required if we are to make multilateral price index numbers for the world as a whole, and I
use data from the 2005 ICP to investigate their credibility. My analysis shows that these
comparisons rest on weak theoretical foundations and are fragile in practice.
Section VI returns to the main argument and looks briefly at an alternative monitoring
system based on asking people about their lives are going; I use data from the Gallup World
Poll which collects an annual sample of all the people of the world. Section VII concludes,
and speculates on the global system of income and poverty statistics as a whole. I argue that
we should be less ambitious and more skeptical in using the international data, particularly

Citations
More filters
Book ChapterDOI

Sustainable Development Goals and the measurement of economic and social progress

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors take stock of the SDG process in relation to the general movement towards a broader perspective on the measurement of economic performance and social progress, and three central themes emerge: the inevitable and enduring tension between the pull to broaden and expand indicators for assessing and monitoring economic and Social progress in development, and the imperative to keep a relatively small number of top-level indicators, in order to facilitate national discourse and policy-making, on the other.
Book ChapterDOI

Chapter 1 Refining the basic needs approach: A multidimensional analysis of poverty in Latin America

TL;DR: In this article, the authors proposed three methodological refinements to the unsatisfied basic needs (UBN) approach and provided a set of comparable poverty estimates for six Latin American countries between 1992 and 2006.
Dissertation

Foreign Policy towards Latin America in Europe: A Comparative Study

Bettina Trüb
TL;DR: In this paper, the origins of EU Member States' divergent Latin America policies, as well as their interaction with the EU's strategy towards the region, were investigated using fuzzy-set Qualitative Comparative Analysis (fsQCA).
Posted Content

Global poverty, aid, and middle-income countries Are the country classifications moribund or is global poverty in the process of 'nationalizing'?

TL;DR: The majority of the world's poor now live in countries classified by the World Bank as middle-income countries as discussed by the authors, and the thresholds used to classify them are moribund, meaning they do not represent poor or non-poor countries in any meaningful sense.
Posted Content

Methods of aggregation above the basic heading level with regions

TL;DR: In this article, the 155 Basic Heading (BH) price parities for each of the K countries in a region were constructed for ICP 2005, and aggregate measures of country prices and relative volumes between countries can be constructed using a wide variety of multilateral comparison methods.
References
More filters
Book ChapterDOI

Economic Growth and Income Inequality

TL;DR: The process of industrialization engenders increasing income inequality as the labor force shifts from low-income agriculture to the high income sectors as mentioned in this paper, and on more advanced levels of development inequality starts decreasing and industrialized countries are again characterized by low inequality due to the smaller weight of agriculture in production and income generation.
Book ChapterDOI

Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence

TL;DR: In this article, the authors discuss the association of income and happiness and suggest a Duesenberry-type model, involving relative status considerations as an important determinant of happiness.

Economic growth and income inequality

TL;DR: This article investigated whether income inequality affects subsequent growth in a cross-country sample for 1965-90, using the models of Barro (1997), Bleaney and Nishiyama (2002) and Sachs and Warner (1997) with negative results.
Book

On Economic Inequality

TL;DR: In this paper, Amartya Sen relates the theory of welfare economics to the study of economic inequality and presents a systematic treatment of the conceptual framework as well as the practical problems of measurement of inequality.
Book

The Law of Peoples

John Rawls
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors sketch in a short space how the law of peoples may be developed out of liberal ideas of justice similar to but more general than the idea I called justice as fairness and presented in my book A Theory of Justice.
Related Papers (5)