scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

The American Family and Family Economics

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
The American family has changed radically in recent decades as discussed by the authors and there is an ongoing effort to understand partnering, parenting, and care of the elderly as results of maximizing choices made by individuals.
Abstract
Gary Becker's path-breaking Treatise on the Family (1981) subjected individuals' decisions about sex, marriage, childbearing, and childrearing to rational choice analysis The American family has changed radically in recent decades; we survey these changes as well as the ongoing effort to understand partnering, parenting, and care of the elderly as results of maximizing choices made by individuals First, we describe the recent changes in the American family: the separation of sex, marriage, and childbearing; fewer children and smaller households; converging work and education patterns for men and women; class divergence in partnering and parenting strategies; and the replacement of family functions and home production by government programs and market transactions Second, we examine recent work in family economics that attempts to explain these changes Third, we point out some challenging areas for further analysis and highlight issues of commitment in two primary family relationships: those b

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
THE AMERICAN FAMILY AND FAMILY ECONOMICS
Shelly Lundberg
Robert A. Pollak
Working Paper 12908
http://www.nber.org/papers/w12908
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
February 2007
We are grateful to the members of the MacArthur Network on the Family and the Economy, and to
Joanne Spitz, Dick Startz, Meredith Startz, James Hines, Michael Waldman, and especially Timothy
Taylor for their helpful comments. Pollak is grateful to the John D. and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation
for their support and Lundberg to the Castor Professorship. The views expressed herein are those of
the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
© 2007 by Shelly Lundberg and Robert A. Pollak. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to
exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including
© notice, is given to the source.

The American Family and Family Economics
Shelly Lundberg and Robert A. Pollak
NBER Working Paper No. 12908
February 2007
JEL No. D1,J1,J2
ABSTRACT
The twenty-fifth anniversary of the publication of Gary Becker's path-breaking "Treatise on the Family"
provides an occasion to reexamine both the American family and family economics. We begin by
discussing how families have changed in recent decades: the separation of sex, marriage, and childbearing;
fewer children and smaller households; converging work and education patterns for men and women;
class divergence in partnering and parenting strategies; and the replacement of what had been family
functions and home production by government programs and market transactions. After discussing
recent work in family economics that attempts to explain these changes, we point out some challenging
areas for further analysis, and highlight issues of commitment in two primary family relationships:
those between men and women, and those between parents and children. We conclude by discussing
the effectiveness of policies to target benefits to certain family members (e.g., children) or to promote
marriage and fertility.
Shelly Lundberg
Department of Economics
227 Savery Hall
Box 353330
University of Washington
Seattle, WA 98195-3330
LUNDBERG@U.WASHINGTON.EDU
Robert A. Pollak
Washington University in St. Louis
Faculty of Arts and Sciences
and the John M. Olin School
Campus Box 1133
1 Brookings Drive
St. Louis, MO 63130-4899
and NBER
pollak@wustl.edu

2
Gary Becker’s path-breaking Treatise on the Family subjected individuals’ decisions
about sex, marriage, childbearing, and childrearing to rational choice analysis. Becker’s aim was
to use the foundational assumptions of “maximizing behavior, market equilibrium, and stable
preferences” (1991, Enlarged edition, p. 5) to explain the basic empirical patterns of family life.
1
According to Becker (p. 135), “[T]he main purpose of marriage and families is the production
and rearing of own children . . .” and in his model of marriage, the gains to marriage depend on
specialization and exchange within the family. When Treatise was published in 1981, it was
already apparent that the American family had entered a period of rapid change: birth rates had
been falling for 20 years; cohabitation and childbirth without legal marriage had risen; divorce
had become commonplace; and women, including mothers of young children, were entering the
labor force in record numbers. Becker wrote in his “Introduction” that “the family in the Western
world has been radically altered—some claim almost destroyed—by the events of the last three
decades” (p. 1).
The American family has not been destroyed by these changes, but it has been radically
altered. Family structure has become more heterogeneous and less stable. Long-term marriage
combined with childrearing is no longer a near-universal adult experience, and the intense gender
specialization that characterized the traditional nuclear family of the 1950s now seems archaic.
In a continuation of a long-term trend noted by Becker, the economic role of the family
continued to decrease as the market and the state supplemented or replaced more and more
family functions, from food preparation to old-age support.
We begin by discussing how families have changed in recent decades: the separation of
sex, marriage, and childbearing; fewer children and smaller households; converging work and
education patterns for men and women; class divergence in partnering and parenting strategies;
and the replacement of what had been family functions and home production by government
programs and market transactions.
2
After discussing recent work in family economics that
1
Although Becker began with three foundational assumptions, in his more recent work—for example, Becker
(1996)—he relaxes the assumption of stable preferences. For a discussion, see Pollak (2003).
2
Betsey Stevenson and Justin Wolfers (2007) provide additional evidence on trends in marriage and divorce.

3
attempts to explain these changes, we point out some challenging areas for further analysis, and
highlight issues of commitment in two primary family relationships: those between men and
women, and those between parents and children. We then consider the effectiveness of policies
to target benefits to certain family members (like children) or to promote marriage and fertility.
Changes in the American Family, 1960–2006
The Separation of Sex, Marriage, and Childrearing
In the early days of family economics, models of marriage and fertility reflected widely
accepted social norms that were broadly consistent with social reality. Men were supposed to
finish school, get a job, marry, and have children. Educational attainment and employment were
less important for women, for whom the crucial steps were marriage, childbearing, and
childrearing. Economists assumed that decisions about goods purchases, labor supply, fertility,
and child investments maximized a family utility function subject to family resource constraints.
Single-parent families were the result of divorce, which economists assumed must be due to an
unhappy surprise in the realized value of marriage. Nonmarital childbearing was an anomaly.
Since the 1960s and 1970s, however, a framework that considered sex and childbearing
only within the context of a committed partnership has become increasingly disconnected from
reality. Reliable and convenient contraception and the availability of safe and legal abortion
permitted sex with minimal risk of childbearing and the concomitant long-term commitment to
parenting. These developments reduced the cost of premarital sex and, hence, the cost of
remaining single. Combined with rising income and the increasing independence of women, this
encouraged delayed marriage and delayed childbearing. As an alternative to marriage,
cohabitation provided increasing numbers of couples with the benefits of coresidence per se,
including economies of scale in consumption. In the 2000 Census, unmarried couple households
made up 9 percent of all coupled households, with 11 percent of these being same-sex couples
(Simmons and O’Connell, 2003, p. 1 and table 1).
Nonmarital fertility has risen dramatically in the past quarter century. According to the
CDC National Center for Health Statistics, 37 percent of U.S. births were out-of-wedlock in

4
2005.
3
Though fertility outside legal marriage has become commonplace in many developed
countries, especially in northwestern Europe, most unmarried European couples are living
together when their child is born. In contrast, in the United States, the majority of nonmarital
births are to lone mothers, although the proportion of nonmarital births to cohabiting couples is
increasing (Bumpass and Lu, 2000). This emergence of nonmarital childbearing reflects, to a
large extent, the decline of the social imperative that premarital pregnancy should lead to
marriage. For many men, paternity has been separated from parenting responsibilities other than
financial obligations, which are increasingly enforced by the state.
The increase in nonmarital childbearing and in divorce rates has altered the living
arrangements of children. The proportion of children under age 18 who are living with only one
parent rose from 9 percent in 1960 to 28 percent in 2005. These children also experience many
transitions in where and with whom they live, since most unmarried mothers eventually marry,
and the divorced remarry.
4
With multiple, serial partnerships between parents, families have
become more complex, with uncertain implications for parent–child relationships and
investments in children. Using a recent sample of births to unmarried women, Mincy (2002)
found that the majority of mothers with two or more children had at least one child whose
biological father was not the father of their most recent child. He found that this “multiple
partner fertility” compromised the marriage prospects of these new mothers.
All these factors have combined to increase the heterogeneity of families and to decrease
the stability of the living arrangements in which children are reared. Moreover, with increased
cohabitation, childbearing that frequently precedes the establishment of a long-term partnership,
and an increased propensity for adult children to move back in with parents during extended
education or early parenthood, “the sequencing of adult transitions has become increasingly
complicated” (Furstenberg et al., 2004).
Smaller Families and Longer Lives
3
The percentage of nonmarital births differs by race and ethnicity: 25 percent of non-Hispanic white births, 48
percent of Hispanic births, and 70 percent of non-Hispanic black births were nonmarital.
4
Before the twentieth century, serial partnerships and “blended” families arose from the remarriage of widows and
widowers with children. In the late twentieth century, they arose from the remarriage of divorced men and women
with children, or from the marriage of those who become parents in nonmarital relationships.

Citations
More filters
Journal Article

A Treatise on the Family

TL;DR: A Treatise on the Family by G. S. Becker as discussed by the authors is one of the most famous and influential economists of the second half of the 20th century, a fervent contributor to and expounder of the University of Chicago free-market philosophy, and winner of the 1992 Nobel Prize in economics.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Quiet Revolution That Transformed Women's Employment, Education, and Family

TL;DR: In this article, the authors explored the relationship between the development of modern labor economics and the reality of women's changing economic role and explored whether the revolution has stalled or is being reversed.
Journal ArticleDOI

Overview Chapter 6: The diverse faces of the second demographic transition in Europe.

TL;DR: In this paper, the concept of the second demographic transition (SDT) and its relevance for explaining the ongoing changes in family and fertility patterns across Europe is discussed. But the transition does not necessarily lead to subreplacement fertility levels.
References
More filters
Book

A Treatise on the Family

TL;DR: The Enlarged Edition as mentioned in this paper provides an overview of the evolution of the family and the state Bibliography Index. But it does not discuss the relationship between fertility and the division of labor in families.
Journal ArticleDOI

Are Government Bonds Net Wealth

TL;DR: In this article, the authors consider the effects of different types of intergenerational transfer schemes on the stock of public debt in the context of an overlapping-generations model and show that finite lives will not be relevant to the capitalization of future tax liabilities so long as current generations are connected to future generations by a chain of operative inter-generational transfers.
Journal Article

A Treatise on the Family

TL;DR: A Treatise on the Family by G. S. Becker as discussed by the authors is one of the most famous and influential economists of the second half of the 20th century, a fervent contributor to and expounder of the University of Chicago free-market philosophy, and winner of the 1992 Nobel Prize in economics.
ReportDOI

A Theory of Social Interactions

TL;DR: In this paper, a general treatment of social interactions into the modern theory of consumer demand is presented, where various characteristics of different persons are assumed to affect the utility functions of some persons, and the behavioral implications are systematically explored.
Book

Growing Up With a Single Parent: What Hurts, What Helps

TL;DR: In this paper, the role of parenting and the community connection in single-parenting is discussed and why we care about single-parenthood, and what should be done about it.
Frequently Asked Questions (16)
Q1. What are the contributions in this paper?

The twenty-fifth anniversary of the publication of Gary Becker 's path-breaking `` Treatise on the Family '' provides an occasion to reexamine both the American family and family economics. The authors begin by discussing how families have changed in recent decades: the separation of sex, marriage, and childbearing ; fewer children and smaller households ; converging work and education patterns for men and women ; class divergence in partnering and parenting strategies ; and the replacement of what had been family functions and home production by government programs and market transactions. The authors conclude by discussing the effectiveness of policies to target benefits to certain family members ( e. g., children ) or to promote marriage and fertility. After discussing recent work in family economics that attempts to explain these changes, the authors point out some challenging areas for further analysis, and highlight issues of commitment in two primary family relationships: those between men and women, and those between parents and children. 

The twin assumptions that there are exactly two activities—home and market—and thathusbands and wives provide time inputs that are perfect substitutes (that is, identical on a qualityadjusted basis) to household production is crucial to Becker's specialization results. 

Changing social norms, in particular the decreasing stigma associated with cohabitation,nonmarital childbearing, and lone motherhood, have also reduced the incentive to marry, but recent evidence suggests some additional normative barriers to marriage. 

Recent changes in the family, such as increased divorce and remarriage and theprevalence of nonmarital childbearing, may have implications for intergenerational transfers. 

Nearly two-thirds of the 5.5 million elderly with chronic disabilities rely, often exclusively, on family members for help with basic activities of daily living. 

Using questions in the National Longitudinal Survey about bequest intentions, Light and McGarry (2004) found that about 80 percent of respondents intended to divide their estates equally among their children. 

The supply of family members willing and able to act as caregivers will depend on labor force participation, family size, and family structure. 

Posner goes on to argue that community enforcement depends on a commonly accepted understanding of the behavior expected of spouses. 

Two factors are primarily responsible for this increased heterogeneity and instability: 1) a decline in the value of marriage compared to its alternatives and 2) a decline in individuals’ ability and willingness to make credible long-term commitments to partners/spouses, children, and parents. 

The two-earner couple location problem provides a paradigm for situations in which couples face decisions that affect future bargaining power, such as childbearing, human capital investments, and marriage itself. 

Because family structure is intertwined with other parental characteristics that affect children, a causal relationship between family structure and child outcomes is difficult to establish. 

Stepparents and noncustodial parents may be less motivated to provide resources to children, and children less willing to support elderly stepparents or noncustodial parents, especially those with whom they resided only briefly or not at all. 

They show that even if the second stage is conditionally efficient (that is, efficient given the livingarrangements determined in the first stage), the equilibrium of the two-stage game may be inefficient. 

The question of whether the number of children is optimal has been in the public eye because fertility rates in virtually all developed countries except the United States are below the level that will replace their current populations. 

These reports suggest that, given community norms and peer effects on behavior, low-income unmarried parents are unable to negotiate agreements involving legal marriage that would make both parents better off than remaining unmarried. 

Engers and Stern (2002) develop and estimate a bargaining model of family long-term care decisions that can have both efficient and inefficient equilibria.