scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Trading-Off Volatility and Distortions? Food Policy During Price Spikes

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
This article developed a model to derive how much price distortion a government would introduce when it cares about stability in a situation with limited policy options, and identified the optimal combination of distortions and stability for given international price shocks and interest groups preferences for stability.
Abstract
This paper addresses to what extent governments have traded off price distortions for reduced volatility in intervening in agricultural and food markets during the recent food price spikes. We develop a model to derive how much distortions a government would introduce when it cares about stability in a situation with limited policy options. We show a trade-off and identify the optimal combination of distortions and stability for given international price shocks and interest groups preferences for stability. Empirical evidence shows that several countries have been able to reduce (short run) price volatility in the domestic markets while at the same time allowing structural (medium and long term) price changes to pass through to producers and consumers. However, this is not the general case. For many countries, even when explicitly taking into account the trade-off (and the benefits of reducing volatility) government policies appear far removed from the optimal trade-off and there appears to be much room for policy improvement.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

LICOS Discussion Paper Series
Discussion Paper 359/2014
Trading-off Volatility and Distortions?
Food Policy During Price Spikes
Hannah Pieters and Johan Swinnen
Faculty of Economics and Business
LICOS Centre for Institutions and Economic Performance
Waaistraat 6 mailbox 3511
3000 Leuven
BELGIUM
TEL:+32-(0)16 32 65 98
FAX:+32-(0)16 32 65 99
http://www.econ.kuleuven.be/licos

1
Trading-off Volatility and Distortions?
Food Policy During Price Spikes
Hannah Pieters
1
and Johan Swinnen
1,2
1
LICOS Centre for Institutions and Economic Performance
KU Leuven
2
Centre for Food Security and the Environment
Stanford University
Version: 25 November 2014
Abstract
This paper addresses to what extent governments have traded off price distortions for
reduced volatility in intervening in agricultural and food markets during the recent food
price spikes. We develop a model to derive how much distortions a government would
introduce when it cares about stability in a situation with limited policy options. We
show a trade-off and identify the optimal combination of distortions and stability for
given international price shocks and interest groups preferences for stability. Empirical
evidence shows that several countries have been able to reduce (short run) price
volatility in the domestic markets while at the same time allowing structural (medium
and long term) price changes to pass through to producers and consumers. However,
this is not the general case. For many countries, even when explicitly taking into
account the trade-off (and the benefits of reducing volatility) government policies
appear far removed from the optimal trade-off and there appears to be much room for
policy improvement.
This research was financially supported by the KU Leuven (Methusalem Program) and
the European Commission (FoodSecure FP7). The authors thank Koen Deconinck,
Steve McCorriston, Will Martin and participants at conferences in Ljubljana (EAAE)
and Minneapolis (AAEA) for comments on earlier versions of the paper.
Corresponding author: hannah.pieters@kuleuven.be

2
1. Introduction
A large literature has focused on what Kym Anderson (2009) refers to as “distortions
to agricultural incentives”. A key element of these distortions is how government
interventions cause prices to diverge from “market prices” or “equilibrium prices” and
thus distort incentives for consumers and producers in their respective decisions,
causing inefficiencies throughout the economy. The basic model behind the literature
on price and market distortions is one with static supply and demand equations where
consumption and production adjust in response to long term prices.
However in recent years, much of the discussion on global agricultural and food
prices has focused on the, often short-run, volatility of these prices. It is argued that
such short-run volatility of prices is causing inefficiencies in consumption and prices
as it is difficult for consumers and producers to make optimal decisions in such volatile
environments (Barrett et al., 2013). A typical example is the problem of farmers to plan
their output if prices are volatile and uncertainty is large.
This is not only an issue for producers and consumers but also for governments.
As is well known, all over the world, politicians and governments are regularly under
pressure from agricultural producers and food consumers to intervene in agricultural
and food markets. In the longer run, this has led to a series of “patterns” of policy
distortions in agricultural and food markets (Kreuger et al., 1991; Anderson et al.,
2013). In recent years, many governments have intervened in an attempt to reduce short
run price fluctuations with global food price spikes (Barrett, 2014; Naylor, 2014;
Pinstrup-Andersen 2014)
. These government interventions have often been ad hoc -
Government interventions to counter market fluctuations are not unusual. To the contrary, they are a
key ‘stylized fact’ of agricultural and food policies (Anderson et al., 2013) and there is much evidence
to document this for other periods and regions (e.g. Gardner, 1989; Swinnen, 2009)

3
resembling what Swinnen (1996) called fire brigade policy-making when
governments are confronted with shocks in the external environment.
Many economists and policy advisors have been critical of these attempts,
criticizing governments for (a) being ineffective, (b) causing distortions in the
economy, and (c) reinforcing price fluctuations, etc. (Anderson et al., 2013).
However, at the same time many economists and advisors point at the
importance of reducing price volatility based on efficiency gains (FAO, 2011; FAO and
OECD, 2011; Prakash, 2011; World Bank, 2012). In fact in environments with
important market imperfection (e.g. in insurance and other factor markets) government
interventions that reduce price instability could be efficiency enhancing. (After all that
is why one uses various insurance-type instruments in private markets.) Yet, the basic
economic model with static supply and demand equations and perfect markets is not
very adequate to capture and measure distortions and inefficiencies in such conditions
of market imperfections and volatility
.
The question therefore can be raised to what extent governments have traded
off price distortions for reduced volatility in intervening in agricultural and food
markets. This question has both positive (“is this the case? If so, why ?”) and normative
(“is this good or bad; and why ?”) aspects. In this paper we analyze how much
distortions a welfare maximizing government would introduce when it cares about
stability (i.e. if it wants to limit price volatility for domestic producers and consumers)
in a situation with limited policy options, and we compare this with empirical evidence.
Key findings of our paper are (a) that several countries have been able to reduce
(short run) price volatility in the domestic markets while at the same time allowing
Of course, the more fundamental issue is one of the policy instrument choice and the (transaction) costs
and capacity of governments to implement certain policy instruments.

4
structural (medium and long term) price changes to pass through to producers and
consumers; (b) that there is a trade-off between volatility and distortions in situations
with limited policy options for welfare maximizing governments; and (c) that even
when explicitly taking into account this trade-off (and the benefits of reducing
volatility) that many countries (governments) are far removed from the optimal
distortion-volatility (DV) combination and that there is, thus, much room for policy
improvement.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents two cases of important
staple food markets where governments have significantly reduced (short run) price
volatility in the domestic markets while at the same time allowing structural (medium
and long term) price changes pass through. Section 3 develops a conceptual model of
the trade-off between distortions and volatility for a welfare maximizing government.
Section 4 links the theoretical framework to empirical indicators. Section 5 presents
empirical indicators of the distortions-volatility (DV) trade-off for staple food markets
and develops a single “efficiencyindicator. Section 6 presents the empirical results on
distortions in staple food markets in developing and emerging countries. Section 7
concludes.
2. Trading of Volatility and Distortions: Two Examples
To start, we will illustrate the key issue with two cases of government interventions in
important food markets over the past decade. The first example is that of rice markets
and prices in China; the second example is that of wheat markets and prices in Pakistan.
Figure 1 illustrates the evolution of rice prices on global markets and in China.
The graph illustrates two important observations. First, rice prices in China have been
much less volatile than on global markets. The sharp global price fluctuations in 2008-
2010 have not occurred in China. This was due to important policy interventions by the

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

EU policies and global food security

TL;DR: This article reviewed evidence on the impact of EU policies on global food security, focusing on several EU policy areas: agricultural policy, bioenergy policy, food standards, trade policy, and development (food aid) policy.
Journal ArticleDOI

The idea of food as commons or commodity in academia. A systematic review of English scholarly texts

TL;DR: In this article, a systematic literature review of academic papers since 1900 has been carried out with Google Scholar, using different searching terms related to food, including food as commons and public good.
Journal ArticleDOI

Some dynamic aspects of food standards

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a framework to illustrate some dynamic economic and political aspects of standards in closed and open economies, and suggest explanations for persistent differences in food standards across countries.
Posted Content

Trade Policy Coordination and Food Price Volatility

TL;DR: The authors analyzes trade policy coordination when trade policies are driven by terms-of-trade effects and a desire to reduce domestic food price volatility, and shows that importing and exporting countries have incentives to deviate from cooperation at different periods.
Journal ArticleDOI

Nexus of FDI, population, energy production, and water resources in South Asia: a fresh insight from dynamic common correlated effects (DCCE).

TL;DR: The newly developed approach dynamic common correlated effects (DCCE) by Chudik and Pesaran for measuring co-integration has been applied and provides significant robust outcomes in the presence ofCross-sectional dependence among the cross-sectional units.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The Measurement of Productive Efficiency

M. J. Farrell
Journal ArticleDOI

On the Behaviour of Commodity Prices

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors apply the standard rational expectations competitive storage model to the study of thirteen commodities and find that the prices from one year to the next conform to the predictions of the theory about conditional expectations and conditional variances.
Journal ArticleDOI

Competitive Storage and Commodity Price Dynamics

TL;DR: This article showed that speculative activity can substantially increase autocorrelation for prices that are weakly auto-correlated in its absence, but not to the high levels that are observed in the data.
Frequently Asked Questions (15)
Q1. What are the contributions in "Trading-off volatility and distortions? food policy during price spikes" ?

This paper addresses to what extent governments have traded off price distortions for reduced volatility in intervening in agricultural and food markets during the recent food price spikes. The authors develop a model to derive how much distortions a government would introduce when it cares about stability in a situation with limited policy options. The authors show a trade-off and identify the optimal combination of distortions and stability for given international price shocks and interest groups preferences for stability. This research was financially supported by the KU Leuven ( Methusalem Program ) and the European Commission ( FoodSecure FP7 ). The authors thank Koen Deconinck, Steve McCorriston, Will Martin and participants at conferences in Ljubljana ( EAAE ) and Minneapolis ( AAEA ) for comments on earlier versions of the paper. 

The basic model behind the literature on price and market distortions is one with static supply and demand equations where consumption and production adjust in response to long term prices. 

The extent of the adjustment will depend on the marginal increase in productionand consumption distortions caused by deviations of the price from the world market price (captured by 𝑆′ − 𝐷′, which reflect the elasticities of supply and demand) and the preferences for stability (𝛿 + 𝜇). 

an issue the authors ignored is the spillover effects (and potentially secondary price effects) of domestic policies on international markets, an issue emphasized by e.g. Martin and Ivanic (2014). 

The wheat prices of Egypt, the maize prices of Malawi, rice prices of Vietnam were not included in their sample because of a lack of data over the period from January 2007 and December 2013. 

Their assumption was that to address the volatility governments would intervene in markets and did not have other instruments, such as income support as an alternative option. 

The authors also showed that several countries have been able to reduce (short run) pricevolatility in the domestic markets while at the same time allowing structural (mediumand long term) price changes to pass through to producers and consumers. 

China’s policy intervention in the rice market has the highest efficiencyindicator (74%) which means 26 per cent lower in terms of increased volatility and increased distortions compared to the (theoretically) best outcome. 

the best performer in the wheat market is Pakistan with 70 per cent, i.e. 30 per cent lower thanthe best possible in terms of a reduction of volatility and distortions over the 2007-2013 period. 

volatility can be measured using the coefficient of variation and is defined as the ratio of the standard variation s over the mean µ for a given time period.𝑣 = 𝑠𝜇 (12)There are two disadvantages related to this measure: (1) the measured volatility returns a positive value when the prices remain constant over time (Huchet-Bourdon, 2011)7 

But as distortions should be measured in absolute values (negative and positivevalue distortions should be considered equally distortive), figure 5 present the optimal DV combinations of the absolute values of the domestic volatility and distortions for different values of 𝜃(𝜀) for a given price shock. 

It is argued that such short-run volatility of prices is causing inefficiencies in consumption and prices as it is difficult for consumers and producers to make optimal decisions in such volatile environments (Barrett et al., 2013). 

To relate these theoretical results to empirical indicators, the authors can express theequilibrium condition as a relationship between price distortions and volatility. 

This was due to important policy interventions by theChinese government, including trade policy measures and the strategic use of rice stocks (Yang et al., 2008). 

When the marginal impact on distortions is larger (𝑆′ − 𝐷′ larger and thus 𝜃 larger) adjustments will be smaller – and vice versa.