scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity

Marc J. Melitz
- 01 Nov 2003 - 
- Vol. 71, Iss: 6, pp 1695-1725
TLDR
This paper developed a dynamic industry model with heterogeneous firms to analyze the intra-industry effects of international trade and showed how the exposure to trade will induce only the more productive firms to enter the export market (while some less productive firms continue to produce only for the domestic market).
Abstract
This paper develops a dynamic industry model with heterogeneous firms to analyze the intra-industry effects of international trade. The model shows how the exposure to trade will induce only the more productive firms to enter the export market (while some less productive firms continue to produce only for the domestic market) and will simultaneously force the least productive firms to exit. It then shows how further increases in the industry's exposure to trade lead to additional inter-firm reallocations towards more productive firms. The paper also shows how the aggregate industry productivity growth generated by the reallocations contributes to a welfare gain, thus highlighting a benefit from trade that has not been examined theoretically before. The paper adapts Hopenhayn's (1992a) dynamic industry model to monopolistic competition in a general equilibrium setting. In so doing, the paper provides an extension of Krugman's (1980) trade model that incorporates firm level productivity differences. Firms with different productivity levels coexist in an industry because each firm faces initial uncertainty concerning its productivity before making an irreversible investment to enter the industry. Entry into the export market is also costly, but the firm's decision to export occurs after it gains knowledge of its productivity.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
THE IMPACT OF TRADE ON INTRA-INDUSTRY REALLOCATIONS
AND AGGREGATE INDUSTRY PRODUCTIVITY
Marc J. Melitz
Working Paper 8881
http://www.nber.org/papers/w8881
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
April 2002
The author thanks, without implicating, Alan Deardor, Jim Levinsohn, and Elhanan Helpman for helpful
comments and discussions. Funding from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. The
views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
© 2002 by Marc J. Melitz. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may
be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity
Marc J. Melitz
NBER Working Paper No. 8881
April 2002
JEL No. F1
ABSTRACT
This paper builds a dynamic industry model with heterogeneous firms that explains why
international trade induces reallocations of resources among firms in an industry. The paper shows how
the exposure to trade will induce only the more productive firms to enter the export market (while some
less productive firms continue to produce only for the domestic market) and will simultaneously force
the least productive firms to exit. It then shows how further increases in the industry's exposure to trade
lead to additional inter-firm reallocations towards more productive firms. These phenomena have been
empirically documented but can not be explained by current general equilibrium trade models, because
they rely on a representative firm framework. The paper also shows how the aggregate industry
productivity growth generated by the reallocations contributes to a welfare gain, thus highlighting a
benefit from trade that has not been examined theoretically before. The paper adapts Hopenhayn's (1992a)
dynamic industry model to monopolistic competition in a general equilibrium setting. In so doing, the
paper provides an extension of Krugman's (1980) trade model that incorporates firm level productivity
differences. Firms with different productivity levels coexist in an industry because each firm faces initial
uncertainty concerning its productivity before making an irreversible investment to enter the industry.
Entry into the export market is also costly, but the firm's decision to export occurs after it gains
knowledge of its productivity.
Mark J. Melitz
Department of Economics
Littauer Center
Harvard University
Cambridge, MA 02138
and NBER
mmelitz@harvard.edu

1 In troduction
Recent empirical research using longitudinal plant or Þrm-level data in several countries has ov er-
whelmingly substan tiated the existence of large and persistent productivit y dierences among es-
tablishments in the same narrowly deÞned industries. Foster, Haltiwanger and Krizan (1998)
summarize this research by concluding that “... within sector dierences dwarf betw een sector
dierences in behavior.” In related work, Haltiwanger (1997, Table 1) reports that 4-digit industry
eectsexplainlessthan10percentoftheoverallvariationinthegrowthratesofoutput,em-
ployment, capital stocks, and productivity across establishments in the U.S. from 1977 to 1987.
Complementing this evidence on the extent of within sector heterogeneit y, other studies hav e sho w n
that the bulk of resource reallocations across Þrms remains internal to the speciÞc sector. Davis
and Haltiwanger (1999) summarize this evidence for the U.S. and report that less than 1 in 10 job
reallocations reßect employment shifts acro ss sectors. Levinsohn (1999) reports similar numbers for
most industries in Chile following wide-reaching trade liberalization. Evidence reported in Roberts
and T ybout (1996) and Davis and Haltiwanger (1999) conÞrms that these patterns are not speciÞc
to the U.S. and that substantial within sector reallocations between heterogeneous Þrms are also
prevalent in developing countries.
If these large intra-industry reallocations w ere unrelated to the heterogeneous characteristics of
Þrms, then their separate existence would not necessarily make them important determining factors
of industry performance. On the other hand, if the reallocations are related to Þrm characteristics,
then the nature of the link between the tw o signiÞcantly aects several important aspects of industry
performance. Although the analysis of this link between Þrm characteristics and industry evolution
is an ongoing research program, enough evidence has b een collected to demonstrate its existence and
relevance for industry performance. The main Þrm characteristic found to be empirically linked to
in tra-industry reallocations is Þrm productivit y.
1
The strongest evidence of this link pertains to Þrm
entry and exit decisions. Productivity dierences between entering and exiting Þrms signiÞcan tly
cont ribute to aggregate industry productivit y c hanges over time. Additionally, a large number of
studies have documented a strong correlation bet ween Þrm exit and lo w productivit y (Þrm age
is also correlated with exit: younger Þrms have disproportionately high failure rates). Finally,
some studies have also found evidence that reallocations unrelated to entry and exit contribute to
1
Firm age and capital vintage are other importan t explanatory characteristics that hav e been highlighted in some
studies, although their impact may be limited to their eect on productivity.
1

industry productivity growth b y redistributing market shares among incumbent Þrms.
2
A similar
reallocation process has also been studied at a higher level of aggregation: Basu and Fernald
(1997) Þnd that U.S. aggregate productivit y changes across the business cycle are partly driven
b y expenditure reallocations across sectors with dieren t average productivity lev els. The inherent
inabilit y of representative Þrm industry models to explain the contribution of reallocations to
industry performance has prompted the development of a theoretical literature of industry dynamics
that emphasizes the role of Þrm level heterogeneit y. This literature, along with the previously
mentioned empirical evidence, is reviewed in Foster, Haltiwanger and Krizan (1998) and Tybout
(2002).
This paper adapts one of these recen t industry models with heterogeneous Þrms in order to an-
alyze the role of international trade as a catalyst for inter-Þrm reallocations within an industry. It
then describes how these reallocations aect both industry performance and welfare. The business
press often assumes the existenc e of this catalyst role of trade when describing how exposure to
trade has both enhanced the growth opportunities of some Þrms while simu ltaneously cont ribut-
ing to the down fall or “downsizing” of other Þrms in the same industry. Similarly, protection from
trade is reported to shelter inecient Þrms. Rigorous empirical work has recently corroborated this
anecdotal evidence. Bernard and Jensen (1999a) (for the U.S.), Aw, Ch ung and Roberts (2000) (for
Taiw an), and Clerides, Lach and T ybout (1998) (for Colom bia, Mexico, and Morocco) all Þnd evi-
dence that the causation of the correlation between Þrm productivity and export status runs from
theformertothelatter: moreproductiveÞrms self-select into the export market. Aw, Chung and
Roberts (2000) also Þnd evidence suggesting that exposure to trade forces the least productive Þrms
to exit the industry (Þrms with higher productivity levels relativ e to the incumbent average exit
after the exposure to trade). Both of these selection eects (into the export market and out of the
industry) obviously reallocate market shares from less productive Þrms(whoexit)tomoreproduc-
tive ones (who export) and therefore contribute to industry productivity growth.
3
P av cnik (2002)
directly looks at the contribution of market share reallocations to sectoral productivity growth
follow ing trade liberalization in Chile. She Þnds that these reallocations signiÞcan tly contribute to
productivity growth in the tradable sectors. In a related study, Bernard and Jensen (1999b) Þnd
that within-sector mark et share reallocations towards more productive exporting plants accounts
2
The importance of this phenomenon varies across studies and is cyclically sensitive (see Foster, Haltiwanger and
Krizan (1998))
3
Forces other than trade also aect the reallocation of resources within an industry. Olley and Pakes (1996) Þnd
that deregulation in the U.S. telecommunications industry increased productivity predominantly through this channel
rather than through intra-Þrm productivity gains.
2

for 20% of U.S. manufacturing productivity gro wth.
By relying on a representative Þrm framew ork (at least at the level of the industry), general
equilibrium trade models have largely ignored these intra-industry reallocations and focused instead
on other consequences of trade, such as inter-industry reallocations or phenomena aecting all Þrms
in similar ways.
4
This paper attempts to Þll this gap by providing a general equilibrium model
with heterogeneous Þrms that explains how trade induces these selection eects and in tra-industry
reallocations. This model shows how exposure to trade will induce only the more productive Þrms
to enter the export markets (while some less productive Þrms continue to produce only for the
domestic market) and will sim u ltaneously force the least productive Þrms to exit. The paper then
shows how further increases in the industry’s exposure to trade (drive n either by trade liberalization
or the addition of new trading partners) lead to additional inter-Þrm reallocations towards more
productive Þrms. The model th u s explains how trade can generate industry productivity growth
without necessarily aecting in tra-Þrm eciency. It also provides a theoretical foundation for
the recent empirical Þndings described above and rigorously shows how trade can contribute to
the Darwinian evolution of industries forcing the least ecient Þrms to con tract or exit while
promoting the growth and success of the more ecient ones.
Another recen t paper by Bernard, Eaton, Jenson and Kortum (2000) also introduces Þrm-level
heterogeneity into a model of trade b y adapting a Ricardian model to Þrm-speciÞccomparative
advantage. Both papers predict the same basic kinds of trade-induced reallocations, although the
ch annels and motiv ations behind these reallocations vary. In addition, Bernard et al. (2000) sho w
how their model can be calibrated to provide a good ÞttoacombinationofmicroandmacroUS
data patterns. Ho wev er, subsequent work b y Brooks (2001) has sho wn that this feature is not
robust across countries. The current paper relies on the previously docume nted empirical micro
patterns and focuses on the theoretical explanations and motivations behind these patterns.
4
This last category includes models that assume a direct link between trade and Þrm lev el eciency. In these
models, exposure to trade typically increases the eciency level of all Þrms through a variety of channels: learning
eects, increased scale of production, increased innovation, higher quality or diversity of intermediate inputs, reduction
of agency problems between owners and managers. Clerides, Lach and Tybout (1998) and Bernard and Jensen (1999a)
speciÞcally test whether new exporting Þrmsbecomemoreecient. Neither of these studies Þnds evidence supporting
this hypothesis. Tybout and Westbrook (1995) test and reject the hypothesis that increased productivity in Mexico’s
growing export industries was driven by increases in the scale of plant production.
3

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms

TL;DR: In this article, Helpman et al. introduce a simple multicountry, multisector model, in which firms face a proximity-concentration trade-off between exports and FDI.
Journal ArticleDOI

The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States

TL;DR: This paper analyzed the effect of Chinese import competition between 1990 and 2007 on US local labor markets, exploiting cross-market variation in import exposure stemming from initial diffe cerence to US labor markets.
Journal ArticleDOI

What Determines Productivity

TL;DR: The authors surveys and evaluates recent empirical work addressing the question of why businesses differ in their measured productivity levels, and lays out what I see are the major questions that research in the area should address going forward.
Journal ArticleDOI

Market Size, Trade, and Productivity

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors develop a monopolistically competitive model of trade with firm heterogeneity and endogenous differences in the "toughness" of competition across markets, in terms of the number and average productivity of competing firms.
ReportDOI

Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India

TL;DR: This paper measured sizable gaps in marginal products of labor and capital across plants within narrowly defined industries in China and India compared with the United States, and calculated manufacturing TFP gains of 30%-50% in China, and 40%-60% in India.
References
More filters
Posted Content

Why Some Firms Export

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a dynamic model of the export decision by a profit-maximizing firm using a panel of U.S.manufacturing plants, and test for the role of plant characteristics, spillovers from neighboring exporters, entry costs and government export promotion expenditures.
Journal ArticleDOI

Exit, selection, and the value of firms

TL;DR: In this paper, a competitive dynamic model with firm level uncertainty and derives implications for the distribution of firm values and Tobin's q. Allowing for entry and exit, the model determines endogenously the degree of selection.
ReportDOI

The deaths of manufacturing plants

TL;DR: This article examined the causes of manufacturing plant deaths within and across industries in the U.S. from 1977-1997 and found that the probability of shutdowns is higher in industries that face increased competition from low-income countries, especially for low-wage, labor-intensive plants within those industries.
BookDOI

What makes exports boom

TL;DR: In particular, the export response to a given stimulus is shaped by the cross-firm dispersion in unit production costs, the extent of product differentiation, and the prevalence of previous exporting experience as mentioned in this paper.
Posted Content

Plants and productivity in international trade

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors reconcile international trade theory with findings of enormous plant-level heterogeneity in exporting and productivity, and fit the model to bilateral trade among the United States and its 46 major trade partners, and see how well it can explain basic facts about U.S. plants: (i) productivity dispersion, (ii) the productivity advantage of exporters, (iii) the small fraction who export, and (iv) a small fraction of revenues from exporting among those that do).
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (10)
Q1. What are the contributions in "Nber working paper series the impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity" ?

This paper builds a dynamic industry model with heterogeneous firms that explains why international trade induces reallocations of resources among firms in an industry. The paper shows how the exposure to trade will induce only the more productive firms to enter the export market ( while some less productive firms continue to produce only for the domestic market ) and will simultaneously force the least productive firms to exit. The paper also shows how the aggregate industry productivity growth generated by the reallocations contributes to a welfare gain, thus highlighting a benefit from trade that has not been examined theoretically before. The paper adapts Hopenhayn 's ( 1992a ) dynamic industry model to monopolistic competition in a general equilibrium setting. In so doing, the paper provides an extension of Krugman 's ( 1980 ) trade model that incorporates firm level productivity differences. It then shows how further increases in the industry 's exposure to trade lead to additional inter-firm reallocations towards more productive firms. 

some studies have also found evidence that reallocations unrelated to entry and exit contribute to 1Firm age and capital vintage are other important explanatory characteristics that have been highlighted in some studies, although their impact may be limited to their effect on productivity. 

As ϕ∗ increases, the probability of successful entry (pin = 1−G(ϕ∗)) decreases average proÞts must therefore increase for Þrms to remain indifferent about entry. 

This export market selection effect and the domestic market selection effect (of Þrms out of the industry) both reallocate market shares towards more efficient Þrms and contribute to an aggregate productivity gain. 

Since the average revenue level is always positive (even when ϕ∗ → 0), the ratio of the average to cutoff Þrm revenue becomes inÞnite as ϕ∗ goes to zero: 

These trade-induced reallocations towards more efficient Þrms explain why trade may generate aggregate productivity gains without necessarily improving the productive efficiency of individual Þrms. 

Although the direction of the change in product variety is ambiguous (product variety will decrease so long as the ZCP curve is downward sloping), the decrease in aggregate productivity is enough to unambiguously entail a welfare loss (see appendix for proof). 

The absence of an upper bound on productivity is assumed only for simplicity; an upper bound can be incorporated in the analysis without qualitatively changing any of the main results. 

Tybout and Westbrook (1995) test and reject the hypothesis that increased productivity in Mexico s growing export industries was driven by increases in the scale of plant production. 

Hopenhayn shows how these dynamics shape the equilibrium distribution of Þrm productivity and analyzes the impact of these dynamics on Þrm value and the performance of cohorts of Þrms over time.