scispace - formally typeset
Journal ArticleDOI

The Science of "Muddling Through"

Charles E. Lindblom
- 21 Jan 1959 - 
- Vol. 19, Iss: 2, pp 79
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
Lindblom, C.E. as mentioned in this paper discussed the science of "muddling through" in the context of monetary policy. But he did not consider monetary policy with respect to inflation.
Abstract
Originally published as Lindblom, C.E. (1959). "The science of "muddling" through," Public Administration Review, 19(2): 79-88. Reprinted with kind permission. For a critical analysis of this issue's Classic Paper "The Science of 'Muddling' Through" by Charles E. Lindblom, please refer to Ronald J. Scott, Jr.'s article "The Science of Muddling Through Revisited" on pages 5-18. SUPPOSE an administrator is given responsibility for formulating policy with respect to inflation. He might start by trying to list all related values in order of importance, e.g., full employment, reasonable business profit, protection of small savings, prevention of a stock market crash. Then all possible policy outcomes could be rated as more or less efficient in attaining a maximum of these values. This would of course require a prodigious inquiry into values held by members of society and an equally prodigious set of calculations on how much of each value is equal to how much of each other value. He could then proceed to outline all possible policy alternatives. In a third step, he would undertake systematic comparison of his multitude of alternatives to determine which attains the greatest amount of values. In comparing policies, he would take advantage of any theory available that generalized about classes of policies. In considering inflation, for example, he would compare all policies in the light of the theory of prices. Since no alternatives are beyond his investigation, he would consider strict central control and the abolition of all prices and markets on the one hand and elimination of all public controls with reliance completely on the free market on the other, both in the light of whatever theoretical generalizations he could find on such hypothetical economies. Finally, he would try to make the choice that would in fact maximize his values. An alternative line of attack would be to set as his principal objective, either explicitly or without conscious thought, the relatively simple goal of keeping prices level. This objective might be compromised or complicated by only a few other goals, such as full employment. He would in fact disregard most other social values as beyond his present interest, and he would for the moment not even attempt to rank the few values that he regarded as immediately relevant. Were he pressed, he would quickly admit that he was ignoring many related values and many possible important consequences of his policies. As a second step, he would outline those relatively few policy alternatives that occurred to him. He would then compare them. In comparing his limited number of alternatives, most of them familiar from past controversies, he would not ordinarily find a body of theory precise enough to carry him through a comparison of their respective consequences. Instead he would rely heavily on the record of past experience with small policy steps to predict the consequences of similar steps extended into the future. Moreover, he would find that the policy alternatives combined objectives or values in different ways. For example, one policy might offer price level stability at the cost of some risk of unemployment; another might offer less price stability but also less risk of unemployment. Hence, the next step in his approach-the final selection- would combine into one the choice among values and the choice among instruments for reaching values. It would not, as in the first method of policymaking, approximate a more mechanical process of choosing the means that best satisfied goals that were previously clarified and ranked. Because practitioners of the second approach expect to achieve their goals only partially, they would expect to repeat endlessly the sequence just described, as conditions and aspirations changed and as accuracy of prediction improved. By Root or by Branch For complex problems, the first of these two approaches is of course impossible. …

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Rapid Information Technology Change, Coping Mechanisms, and the Emerging Technologies Group

TL;DR: The research found that organizations with a group dedicated to investigating emerging IT cope more extensively, but not more successfully, than do those without one, and suggests the need to achieve more from the group charged with emerging IT.
Journal ArticleDOI

Theory into practice, practice to theory : action research in method development

TL;DR: It is illustrated how relevant theory from a range of disciplines can inform practice, and how the process of implementing theory into method develops theory.
Journal ArticleDOI

Suburbs without a City: Power and City-County Consolidation

TL;DR: In this article, the authors analyze the recent city-county consolidation of Louisville and Jefferson County, Kentucky and focus on three critical realignments associated with merging the city and its surrounding county.
Journal ArticleDOI

Analytical strategic environmental assessment (ANSEA) developing a new approach to SEA

TL;DR: In this article, the ANSEA approach provides a framework for analysing and assessing the decision-making processes of policies, plans and programmes (PPP) to enhance environmental integration into the decision making process, decision windows can be identified.
Journal ArticleDOI

Environmental leaders and pioneers: agents of change?

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors distinguish between states acting as environmental leaders or pioneers, while leaders usually actively seek to attract followers, this is not normally the case for pioneers, as states may take on the position of a laggard, pioneer, pusher or symbolic leader.