scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Changes in the distribution of male and female wages accounting for employment composition using bounds

TLDR
The authors examined changes in the distribution of wages using bounds to allow for the impact of nonrandom selection into work and found evidence of an increase in inequality within education groups, changes in educational differentials, and increases in the relative wages of women.
Abstract
This paper examines changes in the distribution of wages using bounds to allow for the impact of nonrandom selection into work. We show that worst case bounds can be informative. However, because employment rates in the United Kingdom are often low, they are not informative about changes in educational or gender wage differentials. Thus we explore ways to tighten these bounds using restrictions motivated from economic theory. With these assumptions, we find convincing evidence of an increase in inequality within education groups, changes in educational differentials, and increases in the relative wages of women.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

CHANGES IN THE DISTRIBUTION OF MALE AND
FEMALE WAGES ACCOUNTING FOR EMPLOYMENT
COMPOSITION USING BOUNDS
R
ichard Blundel
l
Amanda Goslin
g
Hidehiko Ichimura
Costas Meghir
THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES
WP04/25

Changes in the Distribution of M ale and Female Wages
Accoun ting for Emplo ymen t Composition Using Bounds
Richard Blund ell
Amanda Gosling
Hidehiko Ichim ura
§
Costas Meghir
April 2006
Abstract
This paper examines changes in the distribution of wages using bounds to allow for t he
impact of non-random selection into work. We show that worst case b ounds can b e infor-
mative. However, since employment rates in the UK are often low th ey are not inform a tive
about changes in educational or gender wage dierentials. Thus we explore ways to tighten
these bounds using restrictions motivated from economic theory. With these assumptions
we nd convincing evi den ce of an in creas e in inequality within e duc ation groups, changes in
educational dierentials an d increa ses in th e relative wa ges of women.
Acknowledgments: We would like to thank three anonymous referees, Jaap Abbring, Daron Acemoglou,
Manuel Arellano, Jam es H eckman, Jo el H orowitz, Chuck M anski, W hitney Ne wey, E lie Tamer for useful comm ents
and discussion as well as pa rticipants in numerous seminars including the Ec onome tric Society Europ ean m eeting
in M adrid 2004, the mee ting of the E urop ea n A sso ciation of Labour E conomists in Lisbo n 20 04, the S tanford
Institute for Theoretical Eco nom ics 2002 and seminars at UC L, Johns Ho pkins and Northwestern Universities,
the Eco nometric Study G ro up in Lond o n 2004 a s well as pa rticipants in the conference o n Inferrence in Partially
Identied M o dels, Northwestern University, Fall 2005. Funding for this resea rch was provided by the ESRC centre
for the analysis of F iscal Policy at the IF S. D ata from the F ES ma de available from the CS O through t he ES RC data
archive has been used by pe rmission o f the C ontroller of HM S O. We are respo nsible for all errors an d interpretation s.
UCL and IFS, r.blundell@uc l.ac.uk
Essex U niversity, IFS and C EP R, agosling@essex.ac.uk
§
UCL and IFS, h.ichimura@ucl.ac.uk
UCL, IFS an d CE PR, c.meghir@ucl.ac.uk
1

1 Introduction and motivation
Economies suc h as the US and the UK have seen large and unprecedented increases in wag e in-
equalit y amongst w orkers over the la st 30 to 40 years. This is illustrated in Figure 1 where we
show the wa y that the interquartile ranges of male and female log hourly wages have evolved for
thosewhoworkintheUK.
0.4
0.45
0.5
0.55
0.6
0.65
0.7
0.75
0.8
78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98
Men Women
Figure 1: Interquartile range of log wages
These increases in inequalit y have been associated with increased returns to education, cohort
eects and increases in the returns to unobserv ed skill.
1
A v ariety of interpretations have been
given as to why these events ha ve occ urred; these include skill biased technical change, globaliza-
tion induced increased in competition for low skill workers and changes in the supply of graduates.
Gosling, Mac hin and Meghir (2000) show that the increases in the UK can be attributed to per-
1
See Juhn, M urphy and Pierce (1993) for the US and G osling, M achin and M eghir (2000) for th e UK .
2

manent dierences across cohorts and in ch anges in the returns to education. A t the same time
the gap between the wages of working men and working women have fallen.
2
In parallel with these momento us changes in the distribution of observed wages, employm ent
rates for males and females and the composition of the workforce have changed. Employment for
men aged 22 to 59 has decreased from 93% in 1978 to 83% in 2000. This decline is not conned
to older men and reects more than the increase in early retirement. Women on the other hand,
especially those below 30, sa w an increase in their emplo yment. In Figure 2 we show the age
prole for employment for 1978 and for 2000 by gender.
Thedeclineinemploymentsincethelate1970shasitssourcesinanumberofpossiblecauses
that in teract with each other. The large demand shock of the early 1980s combined with the
w elfare system and the wage setting institutions at the time to cause persistent unemploym ent.
3
A
mechanism propagating such persistence and relating to older individuals was the steady increase
of those receiving sickness and disability benets during the 1980s, from whic h there is little
incentive to drop out and return to work.
4
Blundell, Reed and Stok er (2003) also emphasize the
role of the reforms to the housing market and in particular the change since 1983 in rent setting for
the public sector , leading to a large and steady increase in rents over the 1980s and 1990s. Rents
for those on lo w income are subsidized through housing benet, which carries an implicit tax rate
on earnings of 95% when combined with other welfare programmes.
5
The reform inadverten tly
led to a steady increase over time in the range of earn ings ove r which some groups of people
faced high marginal tax rates. This would ha ve aected both the level and the composition of
participan ts.
6
These institutional changes aected older cohorts disproportionately because they
were ov er-represented in the public sector housing, partly explaining the more rapid decline in
2
See Ha rkness (1996 ) for the UK and Blau (1998) and Blau and Kahn (1997) for the U S.
3
see Jackman , Laya rd and Nickell (1991).
4
see Disney and Webb (1991)
5
Housing b enet on its own has a margin al withdrawal rate of 65%.
6
Tho se w ith children an d th ose in h igh re nt areas have ex perienced large relative increases in out of work benet
incom e.
3

emplo yment for older peop le. The above factors, will ha ve aected older and unskilled indiv iduals
more than the rest, although not exclusively, because out of work b enet income increased for all.
Figure 3 illustrates that the ch ange in employment has been heavily skill biased. In this
paper we dene skill by three education groups: those leaving full time education at or before 16
(statutory schooling), those who completed education sometime between 17 and 18 (high school
graduates) and those who completed full time education after 18 (some college). For women most
of the increase in employment can be accounted for by the increase in employment of women
with more than the minimal level of education. The employment rate of the statutory schooling
group has shown a slight decline over the entire time period. Blundell, Duncan and Meghir
(1998) document changes in the incen tive structure. Moreover, it is possible that the gradual
implementation and enforcement of anti-discrimination practices, formally introduced in the 1970s
may have made career progression for skilled women more of a reality over this time period (see
Stewart and Greenhalgh, 1984) .
As the composition of the workforce changes so will in general the observed distribution of
wages for workers, whether the aggregate participation rate changes or not. This obscures the
ch a n ges in the actual/uncensored distribution of wages, preven ting us from understanding the
nature of the change in inequality and the associated changes in educational, age and gender w age
dierentials. A recent example which shows how important such selection issues can be for wages
is the paper by Blundell, Reed and Stoker (2003).
Selection eects have been central to labour economics ever since the pioneering work of
Gronau (1974) and Heckman (1974, 1979). Approaches are either parametric
7
or semi/non-
parametric.
8
Unfortunately, structural economic models fall short of delive ring the assump tio ns
required for identication. Taking a stand on the labour mark et paradigm is generally not sucient
7
See He ckman ( 1979) or Heckman and Sedlacek (1985).
8
See for exam ple, Powell (198 7), N ewey (1988), Das, Newey a nd Powell (200 3), Heckman (1990), Choi ( 1990),
Ichimura and Lee (199 1), Coslett (1991 ), Ahn and Powell (1993).
4

Citations
More filters
Posted Content

Evolution and Rationality Some Recent Game-Theoretic Results. Identification and Estimation of Local Average Treatment Effects

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigated conditions sufficient for identification of average treatment effects using instrumental variables and showed that the existence of valid instruments is not sufficient to identify any meaningful average treatment effect.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Gender Wage Gap: Extent, Trends, and Explanations

TL;DR: In this article, the authors used Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) microdata over the 1980-2010 period to provide new empirical evidence on the extent of and trends in the gender wage gap, which declined considerably during this time.
Journal ArticleDOI

Trade Induced Technical Change? The Impact of Chinese Imports on innovation, IT and Productivity

TL;DR: This paper examined the impact of Chinese import competition on broad measures of technical change (patenting, IT, and TFP) using new panel data across twelve European countries from 1996 to 2007 and found that the absolute volume of innovation increases within the firms most affected by Chinese imports in their output markets.
Posted ContentDOI

The Gender Wage Gap: Extent, Trends, and Explanations

TL;DR: In this article, the authors provide new empirical evidence on the extent of and trends in the gender wage gap, using PSID microdata over the 1980-2010, which shows that women's work force interruptions and shorter hours remain significant in high skilled occupations, possibly due to compensating differentials.
Posted Content

Revisiting the German Wage Structure

TL;DR: In this paper, a 2% sample of social security records is used to show that the wage distribution in West Germany has remained stable throughout the 80s and 90s, but only at the top of the distribution.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error

James J. Heckman
- 01 Jan 1979 - 
TL;DR: In this article, the bias that results from using non-randomly selected samples to estimate behavioral relationships as an ordinary specification error or "omitted variables" bias is discussed, and the asymptotic distribution of the estimator is derived.
Book

Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education

TL;DR: In this paper, the effects of investment in education and training on earnings and employment are discussed. But the authors focus on the relationship between age and earnings and do not explore the relation between education and fertility.
Book

Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a review of the macroeconomics of the post-war unemployment in OECD countries and discuss the policies to cut the job search duration and the structure of the job market.
Book ChapterDOI

The Economics and Econometrics of Active Labor Market Programs

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examine the impacts of active labor market policies, such as job training, job search assistance, and job subsidies, and the methods used to evaluate their effectiveness.
Posted Content

Evolution and Rationality Some Recent Game-Theoretic Results. Identification and Estimation of Local Average Treatment Effects

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigated conditions sufficient for identification of average treatment effects using instrumental variables and showed that the existence of valid instruments is not sufficient to identify any meaningful average treatment effect.
Frequently Asked Questions (11)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Female wages accounting for employment composition using bounds" ?

This paper examines changes in the distribution of wages using bounds to allow for the impact of non-random selection into work. The authors show that worst case bounds can be informative. The authors would like to thank three anonymous referees, Jaap Abbring, Daron Acemoglou, Manuel Arellano, James Heckman, Joel Horowitz, Chuck Manski, Whitney Newey, Elie Tamer for useful comments and discussion as well as participants in numerous seminars including the Econometric Society European meeting in Madrid 2004, the meeting of the European Association of Labour Economists in Lisbon 2004, the Stanford Institute for Theoretical Economics 2002 and seminars at UCL, Johns Hopkins and Northwestern Universities, the Econometric Study Group in London 2004 as well as participants in the conference on Inferrence in Partially Identified Models, Northwestern University, Fall 2005. Funding for this research was provided by the ESRC centre for the analysis of Fiscal Policy at the IFS. 

The second restriction that helps tighten the bounds to the change in educational differentials is also on the functional form of log wages. 

A direct consequence of the standard labour supply model is that for individuals with identical reservation wages, the ones with a higher wage will be more likely to work. 

Economies such as the US and the UK have seen large and unprecedented increases in wage inequality amongst workers over the last 30 to 40 years. 

The next estimation problem, relevant for computing the bounds with exclusion or monotonicity restrictions is the estimation of the probability of employment and the distribution of wages conditional on the instrument Z which in their case is the out of work income and can be regarded as continuous. 

A mechanism propagating such persistence and relating to older individuals was the steady increase of those receiving sickness and disability benefits during the 1980s, from which there is little incentive to drop out and return to work. 

For women, the bounds never cross and as a result the p-values of their tests are always one implying no restriction can be rejected. 

As asset income is more likely to be an issue for those with very high wages, the authors also consider a weaker restriction, namely that for individuals with observed characteristic x, the median wage offer for those not working is not higher than the13The authors may expect individuals with higher preference for work and low reservation wages to have invested morein human capital in the past and thus to end up with higher wages. 

Thus the authors now derive bounds under the assumption that the distribution of wages decreases monotonically with the wage, i.e.F (w|x, z0) ≤ F (w|x, z) ∀w, x, z, z0 with z < z0. 

It is possible to reject the hypothesis of no change for the High school graduates and more marginally for the other two groups (2nd column) Overall figure 12 demonstrates that either cohort effects or an increasing return to experience are an important feature of the changing wage structure over the 1980s and 1990s at least for some education groups. 

Selection effects have been central to labour economics ever since the pioneering work of Gronau (1974) and Heckman (1974, 1979).