scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Risk and Rationality: Uncovering Heterogeneity in Probability Distortion

Adrian Bruhin, +2 more
- 01 Jul 2010 - 
- Vol. 78, Iss: 4, pp 1375-1412
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
This paper presented a parsimonious characterization of risk taking behavior by estimating a finite mixture model for three different experimental data sets, two Swiss and one Chinese, over a large number of real gains and losses.
Abstract
It has long been recognized that there is considerable heterogeneity in individual risk taking behavior, but little is known about the distribution of risk taking types. We present a parsimonious characterization of risk taking behavior by estimating a finite mixture model for three different experimental data sets, two Swiss and one Chinese, over a large number of real gains and losses. We find two major types of individuals: In all three data sets, the choices of roughly 80% of the subjects exhibit significant deviations from linear probability weighting of varying strength, consistent with prospect theory. Twenty percent of the subjects weight probabilities near linearly and behave essentially as expected value maximizers. Moreover, individuals are cleanly assigned to one type with probabilities close to unity. The reliability and robustness of our classification suggest using a mix of preference theories in applied economic modeling.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Socioeconomic Institute
Sozialökonomisches Institut
Working Paper No. 0705
Risk and Rationality: Uncovering Heterogeneity in
Probability Distortion
Adrian Bruhin, Helga Fehr-Duda, and Thomas F. Epper
July 2007, revised version

Socioeconomic Institute
University of Zurich
Working Paper No. 0705
Risk and Rationality: Uncovering Heterogeneity in Probability Distortion
July 2007, revised version
Authors’ addresses: Adrian Bruhin
E-mail: adrian.bruhin@sts.uzh.ch
Helga Fehr-Duda
E-mail: fehr@econ.gess.ethz.ch
Thomas F. Epper
E-mail: epper@econ.gess.ethz.ch
Publisher Sozialökonomisches Institut
Bibliothek (Working Paper)
Rämistrasse 71
CH-8006 Zürich
Phone: +41-44-634 21 37
Fax: +41-44-634 49 82
URL: www.soi.uzh.ch
E-mail: soilib@soi.uzh.ch

Risk and Rationality:
Uncovering Heterogeneity in
Probability Distortion
Adrian Bruhin Helga Fehr-Duda Thomas F. Epper
July 18, 2007
Abstract
It has long been recognized that there is considerable heterogeneity in individual risk
taking behavior but little is known about the distribution of risk taking types. We present
a parsimonious characterization of risk taking behavior by estimating a finite mixture
regression model for three different experimental data sets, two Swiss and one Chinese,
over a large number of real gains and losses. We find two distinct types of individuals:
In all three data sets, the choices of roughly 80% of the subjects exhibit significant
deviations from rational probability weighting consistent with prospect theory. 20%
of the subjects weight probabilities linearly and behave essentially as expected value
maximizers. Moreover, the individuals are assigned to one of these two groups with
probabilities of close to one resulting in a low measure of entropy. The reliability and
robustness of our classification suggest using a mix of preference theories in applied
economic modeling.
KEYWORDS: Individual Risk Taking Behavior, Latent Heterogeneity, Finite Mixture
Regression Models
JEL CLASSIFICATION: D81, C49
Authors’ affiliation: Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, Chair of Economics, Weinbergstrasse 35, CH-
8092 Zurich, Switzerland, phone: +41 44 632 4625, email of corresponding author: adrian.bruhin@sts.uzh.ch

1 Introduction
Risk is a ubiquitous feature of social and economic life. Many of our everyday choices, and
often the most important ones, such as what trade to learn and where to live, involve risky
consequences. While it has long been recognized that individuals differ in their risk taking
attitudes, surprisingly little is known about the distribution of risk preferences in the pop-
ulation (for an exception see Dohmen, Falk, Huffman, Sunde, Schupp, and Wagner (2005)).
Since preferences are one of the ultimate drivers of behavior, knowledge of the comp osition
of risk attitudes is paramount to predicting economic behavior. Economic models often allow
for heterogeneity, but this heterogeneity is usually confined to remain within the boundaries
of the standard model of preferences, expected utility theory (EUT). The empirical evidence,
however, reveals that heterogeneity in risk taking behavior is of a substantive kind, i.e. some
people evaluate risky prospects consistently with EUT, whereas other people deviate substan-
tially from expected utility maximization (Hey and Orme, 1994). Moreover, it seems to b e the
case that rational decision makers revealing EUT-preferences constitute only a minority of the
population. To improve descriptive performance a plethora of alternative theories have been
developed (for an overview see Starmer (2000)). Unfortunately, no single b est fitting model
has been identified so far (Harless and Camerer, 1994) and, depending on the individual, one
or the other model fits better. This finding poses a serious problem for applied economics.
What the mo deler needs is a parsimonious representation of risk preferences which is empir-
ically well grounded and robust, and not a host of different functionals. Providing such a
parsimonious characterization of heterogeneity in risk taking behavior is the objective of this
paper.
Our method is based on a literature on classifying individuals which has recently emerged in
the social sciences. On the basis of statistical classification procedures, such as finite mixture
regression models, investigators have tried to discover which decision rules people actually
use when playing games or dealing with complex decision situations (El-Gamal and Grether,
1995; Houser, Keane, and McCabe, 2004). The finite mixture regression approach does not
require fitting a model for each individual which is - given the usual quality of the choice data
1

- frequently impossible. Instead, our approach reveals latent heterogeneity by estimating the
relative sizes of distinct behavioral groups and by endogenously assigning each individual to
a spe cific group characterized by a unique set of parameter values.
We apply such a finite mixture regression mode l to choice data from three different exper-
iments, two of which were conducted in Zurich, Switzerland. The third experiment took place
in Beijing, People’s Republic of China. We analyze 452 subjects’ decisions over real monetary
gains and losses, which comprise a total of about 18,000 choices. All three experiments were
designed in a similar manner and served to elicit certainty equivalents for binary lotteries.
Using a fle xible sign-dependent functional as basic behavioral model, we show the following
results.
First, in all three data sets, we find two distinct behavioral types of risk taking behavior.
Second, the ratios of the different types in their respective populations are practically equal
in both the Swiss and the Chinese data sets and amount to roughly 20:80. Third, without
putting any a priori restrictions on parameter values we find that one of the two types, which
comprises about 20% of the individuals in each data set, exhibits near linear probability
weighting functions and value functions. Therefore, this group can essentially be characterized
as expected value maximizers. This result is particularly interesting in the light of Rabin’s
calibration theorem (Rabin, 2000) which shows that expected utility maximizers should be
approximately risk neutral for small stakes typically encountered in laboratory experiments.
Therefore, we label subjects belonging to this group of risk neutral people as “EUT-types”.
Fourth, in each data set, the second group, which comprises about 80% of the individuals,
is characterized by significant deviations from linear probability weighting and can be con-
veniently described as prospect theory types. Fifth, almost all the experimental subjects are
unambiguously assigned to one of the two distinct type s. Measuring the quality of classifica-
tion by the average normalized entropy (El-Gamal and Grether, 1995) we obtain an extent
of ambiguous assignments of less than 5% of the maximum entropy, a value which is, to our
knowledge, unequaled in the literature. Thus, we observe almost no “ambiguous” types, i.e.
individuals that are assigned a high probability (of say 0.4) of being one type and a high
probability (of say 0.6) of being another type are practically absent. This c lean classifica-
2

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Thirty Years of Prospect Theory in Economics: A Review and Assessment

TL;DR: Prospect theory, first described in a 1979 paper by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, is widely viewed as the best available description of how people evaluate risk in experimental settings.
Journal ArticleDOI

Expected utility theory and prospect theory: one wedding and a decent funeral

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors consider the canonical case of lottery choices in a laboratory experiment and assume that the data is generated by expected utility theory and prospect theory decision rules, and jointly estimate the parameters of each theory as well as the fraction of choices characterized by each.
Journal ArticleDOI

Are women really more risk‐averse than men? a re‐analysis of the literature using expanded methods

TL;DR: This article found that women are more risk averse than men, and that the degree of overlap between male and female distributions generally exceeding 80% of the distributions of risk in economics, finance, and decision science.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Nature of Risk Preferences: Evidence from Insurance Choices

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors use data on households' deductible choices in auto and home insurance to estimate a structural model of risky choice that incorporates "standard" risk aversion (concave utility over …nal wealth), loss aversion, and nonlinear probability weighting.
Journal ArticleDOI

Common components of risk and uncertainty attitudes across contexts and domains: evidence from 30 countries

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present data collected in controlled experiments with 2,939 subjects in 30 countries measuring risk and uncertainty attitudes through incentivized measures as well as survey questions, and show that measures correlate not only within decision contexts or measurement methods, but also across contexts and methods.
References
More filters
Book

An introduction to the bootstrap

TL;DR: This article presents bootstrap methods for estimation, using simple arguments, with Minitab macros for implementing these methods, as well as some examples of how these methods could be used for estimation purposes.
Book ChapterDOI

Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a critique of expected utility theory as a descriptive model of decision making under risk, and develop an alternative model, called prospect theory, in which value is assigned to gains and losses rather than to final assets and in which probabilities are replaced by decision weights.
Journal ArticleDOI

Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty

TL;DR: Cumulative prospect theory as discussed by the authors applies to uncertain as well as to risky prospects with any number of outcomes, and it allows different weighting functions for gains and for losses, and two principles, diminishing sensitivity and loss aversion, are invoked to explain the characteristic curvature of the value function and the weighting function.
Journal ArticleDOI

z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments

TL;DR: Z-Tree as mentioned in this paper is a toolbox for ready-made economic experiments, which allows programming almost any kind of experiments in a short time and is stable and easy to use.
Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Risk and rationality: uncovering heterogeneity in probability distortion" ?

The authors present a parsimonious characterization of risk taking behavior by estimating a finite mixture regression model for three different experimental data sets, two Swiss and one Chinese, over a large number of real gains and losses. The reliability and robustness of their classification suggest using a mix of preference theories in applied economic modeling. 

Sign- and rank-dependent models, such as cumulative prospect theory (CPT), capture two robust empirical phenomena: nonlinear probability weighting and loss aversion (Starmer, 2000). 

Since preferences are one of the ultimate drivers of behavior, knowledge of the composition of risk attitudes is paramount to predicting economic behavior. 

the highly non-linear form of the log likelihood causes the optimization algorithm to be rather slow or even incapable of finding the maximum. 

A natural candidate for v(x) is a sign-dependent power functionalv(x) = xα if x ≥ 0−(−x)β otherwise, which can be conveniently interpreted and has turned out to be the best compromise between parsimony and goodness of fit in the context of prospect theory (Stott, 2006). 

EUT preferences should be taken account of alongside prospect theory preferences even if rational behavior constitutes only a minority in the population. 

Note that the model allows to test for both individual-specific and domainspecific heteroscedasticity by either imposing the restriction ξi = ξ, or by forcing all the ξi to be equal in both decision domains. 

The observed fourfold pattern of risk attitudes, depicted in Figures 2 through 4, already suggests that nonlinear probability weighting is a dominant feature of aggregate behavior. 

If the classification procedure worked better for three groups than for two groups, the average normalized entropy should be smaller for C = 3 than for C = 2. 

The log likelihood of the finite mixture regression model is then given byln L (Ψ; ce,G) = N∑i=1ln C∑c=1πc f (cei,G; θc, ξi),where the vector Ψ = (θ′1, . . . , θ ′ C , π1, . . . , πC−1, ξ1, . . . , ξN) ′ summarizes all the parameters of the model which need to be estimated. 

In order to evaluate the quality of classification, the authors calculated the average normalized entropy ANE (El-Gamal and Grether, 1995) defined asANE = − 1 N N∑ i=1 C∑ c=1 τic logC (τic) ,for C groups and N individuals. 

In all three data sets, the individuals’ posterior probability of being an expected utility maximizer is either close to one or close to zero for practically all the individuals. 

By Bayesian updating, the algorithm calculates in each iteration an individual’s posterior probability τic of belonging to group c.