scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

A monetary Minsky model of the Great Moderation and the Great Recession

TLDR
In this article, a strictly monetary macroeconomic model was proposed to generate the monetary as well as the real phenomena manifested by both The Great Recession and The Great Moderation, which can generate both monetary and real phenomena.
Abstract
Steve Keen's model of Minsky's Financial Instability Hypothesis ( Keen, 1995 ) displayed qualitative characteristics that matched the real macroeconomic and income-distributional outcomes of the preceding and subsequent fifteen years: a period of economic volatility followed by a period of moderation, leading to a rise of instability once more and a serious economic crisis. This paper extends that model to build a strictly monetary macroeconomic model which can generate the monetary as well as the real phenomena manifested by both The Great Recession and The Great Moderation.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

A Monetary Minsky Model of the Great Moderation and
the Great Recession
Abstract
Steve Keen’s model of Minsky’s Financial Instability Hypothesis (Steve Keen, 1995) displayed
qualitative characteristics that matched the real macroeconomic and income-distributional
outcomes of the preceding and subsequent fifteen years: a period of economic volatility followed
by a period of moderation, leading to a rise of instability once more and a serious economic
crisis. This paper extends that model to build a strictly monetary macroeconomic model which
can generate the monetary as well as the real phenomena manifested by both “The Great
Recession” and “The Great Moderation”.
Introduction
The financial and economic crisis that began in 2007 brought to an abrupt end a period of
economic tranquility that many macroeconomists had celebrated as "The Great Moderation"
(Luca Benati and Paolo Surico, 2009, Ben S. Bernanke, 2004, Steven J Davis and James A Kahn,
2008, Jordi Gali and Luca Gambetti, 2009). The trend for recessions to become less frequent and
milder abruptly gave way to a sharp decline in output, a doubling of unemployment, and a
temporary fall into deflation.

Monetary Minsky Model of the Great Moderation and Great Recession
2
Figure 1:The Great Moderation gives way to the Great Recession
The causes of this economic calamity will be debated for decades, but there should be little
debate with the proposition that it was not predicted by any variant of mainstream economic
analysis available at the time. It was however a prediction of the non-mainstream "Financial
Instability Hypothesis" (FIH) developed by Hyman Minsky.
Steve Keen’s 1995 model of this hypothesis generated qualitative characteristics that matched
the real macroeconomic and income-distributional outcomes of the preceding and subsequent
fifteen years: a period of economic volatility followed by a period of moderation, leading to a
rise of instability once more and a serious economic crisis; and the wage share of income
declining while non-financial business incomes stabilised and financial sector earnings rose
(Steve Keen, 1995; 2000, p. 93). This model is acknowledged as the reason why Keen was one
of the handful of economists to anticipate and warn of the approaching economic and financial
crisis well before it actually occurred (Steve Keen 2007; Dirk J Bezemer, 2009, 2010; Edward
Fullbrook, 2010).
This paper extends that model to build a strictly monetary macroeconomic model of the FIH,
which can generate the monetary as well as the real qualitative characteristics of both “The Great
Recession” and “The Great Moderation” that preceded it. I begin with an overview of Minsky’s
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
5
2.5
0
2.5
5
7.5
10
12.5
15
Unemployment
Inflation
Unemployment and Inflation
Year
Percent
0

Monetary Minsky Model of the Great Moderation and Great Recession
3
Financial Instability Hypothesis, since many economists are unfamiliar with this non-
neoclassical integrated theory of macroeconomics and finance.
1
The language and concepts in Minsky's theory were also developed completely outside the
mainstream economic debate of the past 30 years,
2
and will therefore appear very foreign to
most macroeconomists today. I hope that readers can look past this unfamiliarity to apply the
spirit of Friedman's methodological dictum, that what matters is not the assumptions of a theory,
but its capacity to give accurate predictions (Milton Friedman, 1953).
The Financial Instability Hypothesis—Genesis
Minsky’s motivation for developing the Financial Instability Hypothesis was that, since the
Great Depression had occurred, a valid economic theory had to be able to generate such an
outcome as one of its possible states:
Can “It”—a Great Depression—happen again? And if “It” can
happen, why didn’t “It” occur in the years since World War II?
These are questions that naturally follow from both the historical
record and the comparative success of the past thirty-five years. To
answer these questions it is necessary to have an economic theory
which makes great depressions one of the possible states in which
our type of capitalist economy can find itself. (Hyman P. Minsky,
1982a, p. 5)
1
In addition to being based on unfamiliar theoretical and philosophical foundations, Minsky’s
work has mainly been published in non-mainstream journals such as the Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics and the Journal of Economic Issues, and minor journals such as the
Nebraska Journal of Economics and Business. Minsky has appeared only twice in the AER:
Hyman Minsky 1957 and 1971.
2
The evolution of Minsky’s hypothesis is discussed in detail in Steve Keen, 1995 and 2001.
Hyman Minsky, 1982b provides his most important papers (the introduction and Chapters 1-5
are sufficient). I also recommend Minsky 1975. His final book Stabilizing an Unstable Economy
Hyman Minsky, 1986, is a far less useful guide to his theories than these earlier works.

Monetary Minsky Model of the Great Moderation and Great Recession
4
For this reason, Minsky explicitly rejected neoclassical economics:
The abstract model of the neoclassical synthesis cannot generate
instability. When the neoclassical synthesis is constructed, capital
assets, financing arrangements that center around banks and money
creation, constraints imposed by liabilities, and the problems
associated with knowledge about uncertain futures are all assumed
away. For economists and policy-makers to do better we have to
abandon the neoclassical synthesis. (Hyman P. Minsky, 1982a, p.
5)
Minsky instead combined insights from Schumpeter, Fisher and Keynes to develop a theory of
financially-driven business cycles which can lead to an eventual debt-deflationary crisis.
The Financial Instability Hypothesis—a Précis
3
Minsky’s analysis of a financial cycle begins at a time when the economy is doing well (the rate
of economic growth equals or exceeds that needed to reduce unemployment), but firms are
conservative in their portfolio management (debt to equity ratios are low and profit to interest
cover is high), and this conservatism is shared by banks, who are only willing to fund cash-flow
shortfalls or low-risk investments. The cause of this high and universally practised risk aversion
is the memory of a not too distant system-wide financial failure, when many investment projects
foundered, many firms could not finance their borrowings, and many banks had to write off bad
debts. Because of this recent experience, both sides of the borrowing relationship prefer
extremely conservative estimates of prospective cash flows: their risk premiums are very high.
However, the combination of a growing economy and conservatively financed investment means
that most projects succeed. Two things gradually become evident to managers and bankers:
“Existing debts are easily validated and units that were heavily in debt prospered: it pays to
lever.” (Hyman P. Minsky, 1982a, p. 6). As a result, both managers and bankers come to regard
the previously accepted risk premium as excessive. Investment projects are evaluated using less
33
This summary of Minsky is reproduced from Steve Keen (1995) with the kind permission of
the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics.

Monetary Minsky Model of the Great Moderation and Great Recession
5
conservative estimates of prospective cash flows, so that with these rising expectations go rising
investment and asset prices. The general decline in risk aversion thus sets off both growth in
investment and exponential growth in the price level of assets, which is the foundation both of
the boom and its eventual collapse.
More external finance is needed to fund the increased level of investment and the speculative
purchase of assets, and these external funds are forthcoming because the banking sector shares
the increased optimism of investors (Hyman P. Minsky, 1982b, p. 65). The accepted debt to
equity ratio rises, liquidity decreases, and the growth of credit accelerates.
This marks the beginning of what Minsky calls “the euphoric economy” (Hyman P. Minsky,
1982b, p. 121), where both lenders and borrowers believe that the future is assured, and therefore
that most investments will succeed. Asset prices are revalued upward as previous valuations are
perceived to be based on mistakenly conservative grounds. Highly liquid, low-yielding financial
instruments are devalued, leading to a rise in the interest rates offered by them as their purveyors
fight to retain market share.
Financial institutions now accept liability structures both for themselves and their customers
“that, in a more sober expectational climate, they would have rejected” (Hyman P. Minsky,
1982b, pp. 120-125). The liquidity of firms is simultaneously reduced by the rise in debt to
equity ratios, making firms more susceptible to increased interest rates. The general decrease in
liquidity and the rise in interest paid on highly liquid instruments triggers a market-based
increase in the interest rate, even without any attempt by monetary authorities to control the
boom. However the increased cost of credit does little to temper the boom, since anticipated
yields from speculative investments normally far exceed prevailing interest rates, leading to a
decline in the elasticity of demand for credit with respect to interest rates.
The condition of euphoria also permits the development of an important actor in Minsky’s
drama, the Ponzi financier (Hyman P. Minsky, 1982b, p. 123; James K. Galbraith, 1955, pp. 4-
5). These capitalists profit by trading assets on a rising market, and incur significant debt in the
process. The servicing costs for Ponzi debtors exceed the cash flows of the businesses they own,
but the capital appreciation they anticipate far exceeds the interest bill. They therefore play an

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Variegated anti-austerity : exploring the demise and rise of class struggle during the crisis of neoliberalism

TL;DR: In this article, the authors map important trends that mark a new stage in neoliberal capitalism since 2008, with a focus on class struggle and resistance in the advanced industrial democracies, and present an overview of these trends, highlighting austerity policies and anti-austerity responses.
Journal ArticleDOI

Capital in the Twenty-First Century: Reinterpreting the fundamental contradiction of capitalism

TL;DR: The authors developed a post Keynesian model of growth and distribution showing that once capital is differentiated from wealth, the increase in income and wealth concentration actually occurs when the rate of valorization of financial and real estate assets is greater than the growth rate of real output.
Journal ArticleDOI

Debt and Investment in the Keen Model: a Reappraisal of Modeling Minsky

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examine to which extent the Keen model (Keen 1995) is a faithful modelling of Minsky's Finance Instability Hypothesis and propose a clear interpretation of the debt: households lend unconsumed income to firms to finance their investments.
Journal ArticleDOI

Predicting Major Economic Events with Accuracy: A New Framework for Scientific Macroeconomic Models

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors derive a new category of macroeconomic model and apply it conceptually to explain the causes of economic crises, known as the indeterministic balance sheet plus (IBS+) model.
Dissertation

The Inverted yield curve and hidden Markov models in predicting future bear markets

Olli Rihko
Abstract: Turun kauppakorkeakoulu • Turku School of Economics Bachelor’s thesis x Master’s thesis Licentiate’s thesis Doctor’s thesis Subject Accounting and Finance Date 16.6.2020 Author(s) Olli Rihko Student number Number of pages 93 + Appendices Title The Inverted yield curve and hidden Markov models in predicting future bear markets Supervisor(s) Prof. Luis Alvarez Esteban Abstract Previous studies have shown very clearly that there is a connection between the inversion of the yield curve and future recessions measured as contractions in the GDP. The focus of this study was, however, the connection between financial markets and the inverted yield curve, which has not been studied as much as the production related dependences. Although it is difficult to draw a clear line between stock market crashes and the preceding inversions of the yield curve, the data suggests that the inverted yield curve is a sign of more volatile times ahead, which clearly heightens the risk of a major stock market downturn. The empirical part of the study combined other factors and tools – hidden Markov models, credit spreads, S&P 500 returns, NY Fed recession probability model and the CAPE ratio – with the inverted yield curve in order to improve the predictability of future stock market crashes, which was then used to construct allocation strategies between the stock market and risk-free US Treasury rates. The proposed strategies managed to beat the benchmark and the conducted transaction cost sensitivity analysis proves that the strategies are feasible at reasonable transaction cost levels. The greater annualized returns and lesser volatility of the strategies lead to significantly better risk-adjusted returns than what one would achieve using the simple buy and hold strategy. The obtained Sharpe ratios range from 0,531 to 0,824, whereas the Sharpe ratio of the benchmark total US stock market return is 0,499 during the (pseudo) out-ofsample forecasting period of 1986–2019. It should be noted that the analysis is conducted using past data and the true acid test of the strategies will be made during the current inversion period. Although greater volatility leads to greater opportunities in the market, the effectiveness of the proposed strategies in this study is based on prudence and patience: the best option for the average investor could very well be to weather the storm in safer assets and then return to the stock market once the volatility of the market is lower again.Previous studies have shown very clearly that there is a connection between the inversion of the yield curve and future recessions measured as contractions in the GDP. The focus of this study was, however, the connection between financial markets and the inverted yield curve, which has not been studied as much as the production related dependences. Although it is difficult to draw a clear line between stock market crashes and the preceding inversions of the yield curve, the data suggests that the inverted yield curve is a sign of more volatile times ahead, which clearly heightens the risk of a major stock market downturn. The empirical part of the study combined other factors and tools – hidden Markov models, credit spreads, S&P 500 returns, NY Fed recession probability model and the CAPE ratio – with the inverted yield curve in order to improve the predictability of future stock market crashes, which was then used to construct allocation strategies between the stock market and risk-free US Treasury rates. The proposed strategies managed to beat the benchmark and the conducted transaction cost sensitivity analysis proves that the strategies are feasible at reasonable transaction cost levels. The greater annualized returns and lesser volatility of the strategies lead to significantly better risk-adjusted returns than what one would achieve using the simple buy and hold strategy. The obtained Sharpe ratios range from 0,531 to 0,824, whereas the Sharpe ratio of the benchmark total US stock market return is 0,499 during the (pseudo) out-ofsample forecasting period of 1986–2019. It should be noted that the analysis is conducted using past data and the true acid test of the strategies will be made during the current inversion period. Although greater volatility leads to greater opportunities in the market, the effectiveness of the proposed strategies in this study is based on prudence and patience: the best option for the average investor could very well be to weather the storm in safer assets and then return to the stock market once the volatility of the market is lower again.
References
More filters
Book

General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money

TL;DR: In this article, a general theory of the rate of interest was proposed, and the subjective and objective factors of the propensity to consume and the multiplier were considered, as well as the psychological and business incentives to invest.
Journal ArticleDOI

The General Theory of Employment

TL;DR: In this paper, the theory of interest was restated and the output of capital goods and of consumption was analyzed in terms of uncertainty and fluctuations of investment, and demand and supply for output as a whole.
Book

Stabilizing an Unstable Economy

TL;DR: In his seminal work, Minsky presents his groundbreaking financial theory of investment, one that is startlingly relevant today as mentioned in this paper, explaining why the American economy has experienced periods of debilitating inflation, rising unemployment, and marked slowdowns and why the economy is now undergoing a credit crisis that he foresaw.
Book

Essays in Positive Economics

TL;DR: In this paper, Newman's critical blast blows like a north wind against the more pretentious erections of modern economics, however a healthy and invigorating blast, without malice and with a sincere regard for scientific objectivity.