scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Economic Tracking Portfolios

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
An economic tracking portfolio is a portfolio of assets with returns that track an economic variable as mentioned in this paper, which is useful in forecasting post-war US output, consumption, labor income, inflation, stock returns, bond returns, and Treasury bill returns.
Abstract
An economic tracking portfolio is a portfolio of assets with returns that track an economic variable. Monthly returns on stocks and bonds are useful in forecasting post-war US output, consumption, labor income, inflation, stock returns, bond returns, and Treasury bill returns. These forecasting relationships define portfolios that track market expectations about future economic variables. Using tracking portfolio returns as instruments for future economic variables substantially raises the estimated sensitivity of asset prices to news about future economic variables. Out-of-sample results show that tracking portfolios are useful in forecasting macroeconomic variables and hedging economic risk.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report



Economic Tracking Portfolios - Page 1
Changes in asset prices reflect, among other things, changing information about future
economic conditions. Identifying the impact of different macroeconomic shocks on asset prices
is important because it can reveal sources of economic fluctuations, measure risk premia, and
help predict future economic fluctuations. Economic tracking portfolios are a way of connecting
asset prices with news about economic variables. An economic tracking portfolio is a portfolio
of assets whose returns track an economic variable, such as expected output, inflation, or returns.
The portfolios constructed here have unexpected returns with maximum correlation with
news about future macroeconomic variables. I call these "economic tracking" portfolios, rather
than "factor mimicking" portfolios, to make clear that these portfolios are not only useful for
explaining the statistical properties (means and covariances) of asset returns, but are
fundamentally economic in nature.
Empirical finance has a long tradition of explaining current returns with other current
returns. A second tradition is to try to explain returns with contemporaneous economic
variables, or with future economic variables, or with both (e.g. Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986),
Fama (1990), and Campbell and Ammer (1993)). Economic tracking portfolios represent a
middle ground between these two alternatives. On the one hand, tracking portfolios are asset
returns. On the other hand, they are returns with an interpretable economic content.
Constructing economic tracking portfolios is a way of using current asset returns as instruments
for changes in expectations of future variables. The use of instruments is required because
realized variables are noisy measures of innovations in expectations.
This paper builds on Breeden, Gibbons, and Litzenberger (1989). They construct
economic tracking portfolios (which they call "maximum correlation portfolios") for current

Economic Tracking Portfolios - Page 2
consumption, in order to test the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model (CCAPM). This
paper has several differences. First, and most importantly, it constructs tracking portfolios for
future (not current) economic variables, since asset returns reflect information about future cash
flows and discount rates. Second, as a consequence, it uses only the unexpected component of
returns (not total returns) in constructing the tracking portfolios. Last, it constructs tracking
portfolios for a variety of economic variables (not just consumption).
Tracking portfolios have several uses. One use is measuring risk premia. If tracking
portfolios earn risk premia, then the signs of the risk premia and the identities of the premia-
generating economic variables can reveal which state variables are important determinants of
expected returns, and can help evaluate asset pricing models. Tracking portfolio have (at least)
three other uses that do not rely on the portfolios earning non-zero risk premia.
First, tracking portfolios can serve as hedging tools for individuals who wish to insure
themselves against a particular economic risk. For example, individuals who wish to insure
against inflation could take a position in the inflation tracking portfolio. Second, tracking
portfolios forecast economic variables. Since asset returns are available on a daily basis,
tracking portfolios can provide daily information about the market's expectations about future
economic variables. Third, by measuring innovations in expectations, tracking portfolios
illuminate the structure of the economy and the reaction of prices to economic news. This paper
concentrates on this last use of tracking portfolios, and studies the reaction of stock and bond
prices to news about future production, interest rates, and expected returns.
These three uses are empirically testable, and do not depend on a particular asset pricing
model. For example, suppose the CAPM is true. In that case, an economic tracking portfolio

Economic Tracking Portfolios - Page 3
would have an expected return that is a linear function of covariance with the market, but its
unexpected return would still reveal news about future economic variables. Alternatively,
suppose that asset markets are inefficient, irrational sentiment affects market prices, and returns
are partially predictable. In this case, as long as asset prices reflect some information about
future economic variables, tracking portfolio returns will still be useful for hedging, forecasting,
and understanding the economy.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 1 defines tracking portfolios, states their
statistical properties, and introduces the notation. Section 2 discusses the relation of tracking
portfolios to previous research. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 shows the properties of
the estimated tracking portfolios. Section 5 uses tracking portfolios to test hypotheses about the
effect of news on asset prices. Section 6 shows the out-of-sample tracking ability of the
portfolios, and performs robustness tests. Section 7 concludes by summarizing the results and
discussing possible applications and extensions of tracking portfolios.
1. Definitions and basic properties
Simple tracking portfolios
A tracking portfolio for any variable y can be obtained as the fitted value of a regression
of y on a set of base asset returns. The portfolio weights for the economic tracking portfolio for
y are identical to the coefficients of an OLS regression. If y happens to be to be a state variable
for asset pricing, then a multi-factor model holds with one of the factors being y's tracking
portfolio (Breeden, 1979). However, even if y is not a state variable for asset pricing, its
tracking portfolio is still an interesting economic object, since it reveals changes in market
expectations about y.

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Macroeconomic Factors Do Influence Aggregate Stock Returns

TL;DR: In this article, the authors estimate a GARCH model of daily equity returns, where realized returns and their conditional volatility depend on 17 macro series' announcements and find six candidates for priced factors: three nominal (CPI, PPI, and a Monetary Aggregate) and three real (balance of trade, employment report, and Housing Starts).
Posted Content

The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns

TL;DR: This paper examined the pricing of aggregate volatility risk in the cross-section of stock returns and found that stocks with high sensitivities to innovations in aggregate volatility have low average returns, and that stock with high idiosyncratic volatility relative to the Fama and French (1993) model have abysmally low return.
Journal ArticleDOI

Macro variables and international stock return predictability

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examined the predictability of stock returns using macroeconomic variables in 12 industrialized countries and employed recently developed out-of-sample tests that have increased power, namely, the McCracken [ Asymptotics for out-oftheoretic tests of Granger Causality, Manuscript, University of Missouri-Columbia (2004) and the West [ Econometrica 64 (1996) 1067] test for equal predictive ability.
Journal ArticleDOI

Estimation and Test of a Simple Model of Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing

TL;DR: In this paper, a simple valuation model with time-varying investment opportunities is developed and estimated, assuming that the investment opportunity set is completely described by the real interest rate and the maximum Sharpe ratio, which follow correlated Ornstein-Uhlenbeck processes.
Journal ArticleDOI

Government Spending, Political Cycles and the Cross Section of Stock Returns

TL;DR: In this article, a measure of industry exposure to government spending is used to identify predictable variation in cash flows and stock returns over political cycles, while the opposite pattern holds true during Republican presidencies.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds

TL;DR: In this article, the authors identify five common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, including three stock-market factors: an overall market factor and factors related to firm size and book-to-market equity.
Journal ArticleDOI

On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance

Mark M. Carhart
- 01 Mar 1997 - 
TL;DR: Using a sample free of survivor bias, this paper showed that common factors in stock returns and investment expenses almost completely explain persistence in equity mutual fund's mean and risk-adjusted returns.
Journal ArticleDOI

Time series analysis

James D. Hamilton
- 01 Feb 1997 - 
TL;DR: A ordered sequence of events or observations having a time component is called as a time series, and some good examples are daily opening and closing stock prices, daily humidity, temperature, pressure, annual gross domestic product of a country and so on.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Persistence of Mutual Fund Performance

TL;DR: This article analyzed how mutual fund performance relates to past performance and found evidence that differences in performance between funds persist over time and that this persistence is consistent with the ability of fund managers to earn abnormal returns.
Journal ArticleDOI

Economic Forces and the Stock Market

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors test whether innovations in macroeconomic variables are risks that are rewarded in the stock market, and they find that these sources of risk are significantly priced and neither the market portfolio nor aggregate consumption are priced separately.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (8)
Q1. What is the risk premia of the economic tracking portfolios?

The positive risk premia is one measure of the cost of business cycles: investors demand high returns on assets exposed to macroeconomic fluctuations. 

Theprimary reason for the consumption portfolio's mispricing by the CAPM is that returns on one of the base assets (the one-year treasury bond portfolio) is also mispriced by the CAPM. 

Since the tracking portfolio for production is constructed only using bond returns, the second regression shows the ability of long bond returns to explain stock returns. 

A crucial assumption for the use of tracking portfolios, in equation (1), is that returnsreflect revisions in expectations about the target variable. 

The correlations with baseline portfolios are calculated using monthly returns, where the portfolio weights come from the regression using quarterly returns. 

It could be that stock prices do not react because competing effects on future discount rates and cash flows cancel out in aggregate. 

The other rows of Panel A test whether three subsets of returns forecast the targetvariable (given the other returns): the 12 returns excluding the market portfolio, the eight industry portfolios, and the four bond portfolios. 

Before discussing the results, a statistical fact: since the tracking portfolios are linear combinations of the base assets, the α's of the trackingportfolios are linear combination of the α's of the base assets.