scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Market Segmentation: The Role of Opaque Travel Agencies

TLDR
In this paper, the authors investigate the role of discount travel agencies such as Priceline and Hotwire in the market segmentation of the hotel and airline industries and show that they enable service providers to price discriminate between those customers who are sensitive to service characteristics and those who are not.
Abstract
This paper investigates the role of discount travel agencies such as Priceline and Hotwire in the market segmentation of the hotel and airline industries. These agencies conceal important characteristics of the offered services, such as hotel locations or flight schedules. We explicitly model this opaque feature and show that it enables service providers to price discriminate between those customers who are sensitive to service characteristics and those who are not. Service providers can profit from such discrimination despite the fact that the opaque feature virtually erases product differentiation and thus intensifies competition. The reason is that the intensified competition for less sensitive customers enables service providers to commit to a higher price for more sensitive customers, which leads to higher profits overall. This explains why airlines or hotels are willing to lose the advantage of product differentiation and offer services through discount travel agencies.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Market Segmentation: The Role of Opaque
Travel Agencies
DMITRY SHAPIRO
Belk College of Business
University of North Carolina–Charlotte
9201 University City Boulevard
Charlotte, NC 28223-0001
dashapir@uncc.edu
XIANWEN SHI
Department of Economics
University of Toronto
150 St. George Street
Toronto, ON, Canada M5S 3G7
xianwen.shi@utoronto.ca
This paper investigates the role of discount travel agencies such as Priceline and
Hotwire in the market segmentation of the hotel and airline industries. These
agencies conceal important characteristics of the offered services, such as hotel
locations or flight schedules. We explicitly model this opaque feature and show
that it enables service providers to price discriminate between those customers
who are sensitive to service characteristics and those who are not. Service
providers can profit from such discrimination despite the fact that the opaque
feature virtually erases product differentiation and thus intensifies competition.
The reason is that the intensified competition for less sensitive customers enables
service providers to commit to a higher price for more sensitive customers, which
leads to higher profits overall. This explains why airlines or hotels are willing to
lose the advantage of product differentiation and offer services through discount
travel agencies.
1. Introduction
In the past few years, the emergence of online electronic markets
dramatically changed the leisure travel industry, making it one of the
most developed online businesses. In the United States, online leisure
We are grateful to Mark Armstrong, Danielle Catambay, Stephen Morris, Artie Zillante,
two anonymous referees and an anonymous coeditor whose valuable suggestions helped
us to improve the paper.
C
2008, The Author(s)
Journal Compilation
C
2008 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume 17, Number 4, Winter 2008, 803–837

804 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
travel bookings more than tripled from 2001 to 2005,
1
and are expected to
reach about $69 billion in 2007, or 35% of all online consumer spending.
2
According to PhoCusWright, an independent consultancy, online leisure
travel bookings in the United States will surpass ofine bookings in
volume for the rst time in 2007.
3
Expedia (who owns Expedia.com and Hotels.com), Travelocity
and Orbitz are the three dominant online travel agencies (OTAs). Two
niche players, Hotwire.com (acquired by Expedia in 2003) and Price-
line.com, have emerged that offer services with 3050% price discounts
as compared to ofine reservation prices or prices of other OTAs. These
discount agencies have gained sizeable market shares. According to
MarketMetrix, Priceline and Hotwire combined account for 6.7% of
worldwide online hotel bookings in 2006, comparable to Expedia.com
(10.4%), Travelocity.com (6.8%) and Orbitz.com (4.9%).
4, 5
In November
2007, Priceline reported a gross prot of $479 million and gross travel
bookings of $3.6 billion worldwide for the rst three quarters (a 58.9%
and 40.6% increase compared to the same period in 2006, respectively).
6
The dening feature of Priceline and Hotwire is that they do not
tell customers certain itinerary details, such as brand, time of ight
departure or exact hotel location, until the transaction is completed, and
thus they are often referred to as opaque travel sites.
7
Both sites used
to offer opaque services exclusively, but recently, Priceline (in 2003) and
Hotwire (in 2005) added the traditional transparent retail option with
disclosed prices and itinerary details. Opaque sales nonetheless still
remain a dening identity and major revenue source for both sites. In
2006, for example, Priceline reported that it represented the substantial
majority of our total revenues.
8
1. Source: The New York Times (Late Edition [East Coast]). May 30, 2005. p. C.6.
2. Source: http://www.comscore.com/press/release.asp?press=1545. Press release of
comScore.com from July 30, 2007.
3. Source: http://store.phocuswright.com/phuontrovsee.html. PhoCusWrights U.S.
Online Travel Overview, 2007.
4. Source: MarketMetrics.com, http://marketmetrix.com/en/default.aspx?s=research
&p=research6.
5. These gures likely underestimate the importance of Priceline and Hotwire in the
leisure travel market because they include ve-star hotels that are usually not offered by
opaque sites (with the exception of Las Vegas). The gures also include sales in small
cities where it is infeasible for opaque sites to operateopaque sites need sufciently
many participating hotels to form an opaque product.
6. Priceline.com 2007 Q3 report, Form 10-Q, p. 23 and p. 26.
7. There is a slight difference between the two sites. Hotwire discloses the prices for
opaque hotels or car rentals so consumers do not bid and simply decide whether to buy
or not. Priceline, on the other hand, asks consumers to Name Your Own Price for the
opaque service requested.
8. Priceline.com 2005 annual report Form 10-Q, p. 4, and 2006 annual report, Form
10-Q, p. 2.

Opaque Travel Agencies 805
The opaque feature of Priceline and Hotwire has a strong impact on
the competition between service providers. When the complete informa-
tion about ights (or hotels) is available they are differentiated products.
Hotels differ from each other in their identity, locations and amenities;
ights differ in their departure times, the number of connections, and the
length of layovers. It is well-known that product differentiation reduces
competition and increases prices and prot (Hotelling, 1929). In contrast,
products sold through Priceline and Hotwire are indistinguishable for
customers and become essentially perfect substitutes, which leads to
Bertrand competition and drives down both the price-cost margin and
rms prots.
The question is then: why would hotels and airline companies be
willing to sell their products through Priceline or Hotwire and lose the
advantage (and prot) that product differentiation gives them?
One explanation is that rms use OTAs with the opaque feature to
respond to changes in demand without jeopardizing existing branding
and pricing policies (formalized in Wang et al., 2006). Although this may
be a part of the story we believe that this does not capture the whole
picture. First, Priceline and Hotwire offer tickets during peak seasons
(such as Christmas) and to popular destinations where the demand is
traditionally high. Second, the amount of concealed information is more
than the hotel or airlines identity, which also suggests that the purpose
of these agencies is more than just a facility to anonymously respond to
demand changes.
Another possible explanation is that opaque sites can help sell-
ers reach new consumers with low valuations who otherwise remain
outside the market. The low price of opaque services enables sellers to
attract low value customers who are sensitive to price but less sensitive
to service characteristics. On the other hand, the opaque feature prevents
high value customers from switching to opaque channels because they
would prefer to know itinerary details.
In this paper, we show that opaque agencies enable hotels and
airlines to do much more than just attract low value consumers with
cheap prices. In our model, they act as a collusion device to facilitate
price discrimination between different types of customers and increase
overall prots, even when the total market demand is perfectly inelastic.
We study the role of opaque travel agencies by using a variation of
the Hotelling model. A model of horizontal differentiation is appropriate
in this setting because both hotel and airline competitions are among
service providers with similar qualities. First, Priceline and Hotwire
disclose the star-ratings for hotels service quality and amenities, so
the competition is largely among hotels with similar qualities. Second,
there is little quality difference among major airlines who provide

806 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
the substantial majority of tickets to opaque sites.
9
In particular, all
tickets sold through opaque agencies are economy (coach) class only.
Furthermore, Priceline promises that ights have at most one stop each
way, the layover is no longer than 3 hours, and no red-eye or off-peak
ight are offered unless the traveler agrees to take one.
In this paper, we assume that there is a circle-shaped city where
N hotels are located (Salop, 1979). Consumers have two-dimensional
types: location and transportation cost. Consumers location type comes
from the standard Hotelling model and is continuous. The transporta-
tion cost is binaryeither high or low. We refer to consumers with a
high transportation cost as business travelers, and a low transportation
cost as leisure travelers.
We depart from the standard Hotellings framework by explicitly
modeling the opaque feature of Priceline and Hotwire. In our model,
there is a single opaque travel agency that posts hotel prices and
withholds hotel identities. Customers can make a reservation either
via standard (nonopaque) travel agencies, or using the opaque travel
agency. In the former case, customers can choose a specic hotel, and
other things being equal, they would like to stay at the hotel that is closest
to their preferred location. In the latter case, customers do not know the
hotels location and they simply prefer the hotel with the lowest price.
For a particular range of parameter values, we show that having
an agency with the opaque feature enables hotels to separate high-type
(business) travelers from low-type (leisure) travelers and to gain from
this separation. The source of this gain comes from price discrimination.
Without the opaque agency, hotels compete for both high and low-
type travelers through nonopaque reservation systems. The presence
of the low-type in this market intensies the competition and drives
down the equilibrium price and prot. When an opaque travel agency
(like Priceline or Hotwire) is introduced, a new equilibrium arises
where high-type customers prefer to be served by agencies without the
opaque feature and pay a high nonopaque price. Low-type customers, on
the other hand, are served by the opaque agency that charges lower
prices. The competition through the opaque agency is described by a
Bertrand model, and so in the new equilibrium, hotels competition for
the low-type increases. However, competition in the more lucrative seg-
ment of the markethigh-type travelersdecreases. It is still a Hotelling
competition, but hotels no longer compete for the low-type. Only high-
type customers buy differentiated products and in the equilibrium the
9. The ve largest airline suppliers accounted for 82% of total tickets sold at Priceline
in 2006. See Priceline.com 2006 annual report, p. 16.

Opaque Travel Agencies 807
nonopaque price is higher. Consequently, as long as there is a sufcient
number of high-type travelers, rms overall prot increases.
Importantly, and perhaps somewhat surprisingly, it is the intensi-
ed competition for the low-type which enables hotels to decrease com-
petition for the high-type. Leisure customers enjoy high surplus when
being charged low opaque prices. To attract them to the nonopaque
sector, a hotel would have to decrease the price too much to be prof-
itable. As a result, in equilibrium hotels can sustain the high price of
the nonopaque sector because they no longer use it to compete for
leisure travelers.
The contribution of our paper is threefold. First, we formally model
the opaque feature of Priceline.com and Hotwire.com and investigate
its impact on the competition of the travel industry. Second, within our
framework we nd conditions on the degree of opacity that enables
hotels and airlines to price discriminate using opaque OTAs. We show
that the opacity level cannot be either too high or too low. If the
opacity level is too high, leisure travelers would prefer to use standard
reservation systems, while if the opacity level is too low, business
travelers would nd it optimal to purchase the opaque good. This
nding is consistent with the fact that Priceline/Hotwire do not offer
hotel rooms in small towns and divide large cities into zones. Third, our
analysis helps explain why hotels and airlines are willing to use opaque
channels to distribute their products. In particular, we identify the set of
parameters for which the introduction of the opaque agency increases
the overall prots of the industry.
2. Literature Review
In the literature there are only a few papers that focus on the effect
of the opaque feature of Priceline and Hotwire. Most of them, like
Wang et al. (2006), conduct analysis in the monopolistic setting, whereas
we explicitly model the competition in the travel industry. To our
knowledge, Fay (2008) is the only paper that models the opaque feature
in the competitive environment. In his model, there are two rms and
two types of consumers: those who are always loyal to a particular rm,
and those whose preferences are distributed along the line between two
rms as in the Hotelling model. The transportation cost of all consumers
of the second type is the same.
Our paper is different from Fay (2008) in several aspects. First of
all, we consider a more general framework with any number of rms.
Here the number of rms can be interpreted as the degree of opacity
of the products offered by discount agencies. Consequently, we are

Citations
More filters

Interactive home shopping: Consumer, retailer, and manufacturer incentives to participate in

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examine the implications of electronic shopping for consumers, retailers, and manufacturers, assuming that near-term technological developments will offer consumers unparalleled opportunities to locate and compare product offerings.
Journal ArticleDOI

Revenue Management with Strategic Customers: Last-Minute Selling and Opaque Selling

TL;DR: It is shown that direct last-minute sales are preferred over selling through an opaque intermediary when consumer valuations for travel are high or there is little service differentiation between competing service providers, or both; otherwise, opaque selling dominates.
Journal ArticleDOI

Sell Probabilistic Goods? A Behavioral Explanation for Opaque Selling

TL;DR: It is found that although it is never optimal to use opaque selling when consumers have rational expectations, it can be optimal when consumers are boundedly rational, and it is shown that opaque selling may soften price competition and increase the industry profits as a result of consumer bounded rationality.
Journal ArticleDOI

A Choice-Based Dynamic Programming Approach for Setting Opaque Prices

TL;DR: In this article, the authors use a nested logit model in combination with logistic regression and dynamic programming to illustrate how a service firm can optimally set prices on an opaque sales channel.
Journal ArticleDOI

Opaque Distribution Channels for Competing Service Providers: Posted Price vs. Name-Your-Own-Price Mechanisms

TL;DR: A two-stage model to study the impact of different selling mechanisms, posted price PP versus name-your-own-price NYOP, of an opaque resellers on competing service providers who face forward-looking customers finds that in this environment, providers prefer that the opaque reseller uses a posted price instead of a bidding model.
References
More filters
Book ChapterDOI

Stability in Competition

TL;DR: In this paper, it was shown that if the purveyor of an article gradually increases his price while his rivals keep theirs fixed, the diminution in volume of his sales will in general take place continuously rather than in the abrupt way which has tacitly been assumed.
Journal ArticleDOI

Monopolistic competition with outside goods

TL;DR: In this article, a model of spatial competition in which a second commodity is explicitly treated is presented, and it is shown that a zero-profit equilibrium with symmetrically located firms may exhibit rather strange properties.
Journal ArticleDOI

Reducing buyer search costs: implications for electronic marketplaces

TL;DR: In this paper, the role of buyer search costs in markets with differentiated product offerings is analyzed in the context of an electronic marketplace, and the allocational efficiencies such a reduction can bring to a differentiated market are formalized.
Journal ArticleDOI

Frictionless Commerce? A Comparison of Internet and Conventional Retailers

TL;DR: The authors empirically analyzes the characteristics of the Internet as a channel for two categories of homogeneous products-books and CDs-using a data set of over 8,500 price observations collected over a period of 15 months, comparing pricing behavior at 41 Internet and conventional retail outlets.

Interactive home shopping: Consumer, retailer, and manufacturer incentives to participate in

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examine the implications of electronic shopping for consumers, retailers, and manufacturers, assuming that near-term technological developments will offer consumers unparalleled opportunities to locate and compare product offerings.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "Market segmentation: the role of opaque travel agencies" ?

This paper investigates the role of discount travel agencies such as Priceline and Hotwire in the market segmentation of the hotel and airline industries. The authors explicitly model this opaque feature and show that it enables service providers to price discriminate between those customers who are sensitive to service characteristics and those who are not. The reason is that the intensified competition for less sensitive customers enables service providers to commit to a higher price for more sensitive customers, which leads to higher profits overall. 

In the literature potential explanations to this puzzle include a possibility that hotels can use Priceline and Hotwire to adjust for seasonal changes in demand or to attract new customers with very high price sensitivity. The authors assume that the market size is fixed so that firms can not attract more customers by lowering prices. 

A model of horizontal differentiation is appropriate in this setting because both hotel and airline competitions are among service providers with similar qualities. 

Krishna (1989) shows that quantitative restrictions, such as voluntary export restriction (VER), can impede competition, facilitate collusion and raise prices in a price-setting duopoly. 

If the opacity level is too high, leisure travelers would prefer to use standard reservation systems, while if the opacity level is too low, business travelers would find it optimal to purchase the opaque good. 

Hotel h could profitably deviate by charging a small positive list price which would attract high-type customers located at or close to h. 

From indifference conditions their locations are:x = ph−1 − ph 2tH + 1 2 s; y = ph+1 − ph 2tH + 1 2 s.Given that hotels h − 1 and h + 1 set price equal to pps the maximization problem for hotel h becomesmax ph{ γs( pps − phtH + s ) ph + 21 − γs 1 4 NstL − ph tL ph } . 

the introduction of opaque travel agency in their model can be regarded as a facilitating device that service providers can use to raise prices to business travelers in equilibrium. 

For instance, in case of flight tickets the main source of opacity is concealed itinerary information and is largely unaffected by a withdrawal of one airline. 

For a particular range of parameter values, the authors show that having an agency with the opaque feature enables hotels to separate high-type (business) travelers from low-type (leisure) travelers and to gain from this separation. 

In this paper, the authors show that opaque agencies enable hotels and airlines to do much more than just attract low value consumers with cheap prices. 

One explanation is that firms use OTAs with the opaque feature to respond to changes in demand without jeopardizing existing branding and pricing policies (formalized in Wang et al., 2006). 

The role of the most-favored-customer (MFC) clause as a practice facilitating coordination in a price-setting duopoly has been studied extensively in the theoretical industrial organization literature (for example, Cooper, 1986; Holt and Scheffman, 1987), and the theory is confirmed by Scott Morton (1997a, 1997b), where she finds that the MFC clause adopted by Medicaid for reimbursement leads to an increase in drug prices. 

Trending Questions (1)
How are corporate clients or entities segmented from the point of view of a travel agency?

The provided paper does not specifically mention how corporate clients or entities are segmented from the point of view of a travel agency.