scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Patronage and Elections in U.S. States

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the authors employ a differences-in-differences design, exploiting the considerable variances between states in U.S. states, to find out whether control of patronage jobs significantly increase a political party's chances of winning elections in states.
Abstract
Does control of patronage jobs significantly increase a political party’s chances of winning elections in U.S. states? We employ a differences-in-differences design, exploiting the considerable var ...

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Patronage and Elections in U.S. States
1
Olle Folke
School of International and Public Affairs
Columbia University
IFN
Shigeo Hirano
Department of Political Science
Columbia University
James M. Snyder, Jr.
Department of Government
Harvard University
NBER
September, 2010
1
We thank Don Green, Ken Shepsle, and seminar participants at MIT and Stockholm School of
Economics for their helpful comments.

Abstract
This paper examines whether control of patronage jobs significantly increased a political
party’s probability of winning elections in U.S. states. We employ a differences-in-differencs
design, exploiting the fact that there is considerable variation in the dates different states
adopted civil service reforms. We find evidence consistent with the hypothesis that political
parties in U.S. states were able to use patronage to increase the probability of maintaining
control of their state legislatures and statewide executive offices. We also find evidence that
an “entrenched” party in power for a longer time period can use patronage more effectively
than a non-entrenched party. We consider several alternative hypotheses that might plausibly
account for the patterns in the data, but find no evidence to support them.

1. Introduction
Does the control of patronage significantly increase a political party’s probability of
winning elections? Perhaps surprisingly, at least for the U.S. we do not know the answer to
this question.
Theoretically, it seems hard to believe that the answer could be anything but “Yes.”
Patronage jobs constitute a valuable resource for the party in power. As Pollock (1937, p. 32)
notes: “Employees who are politically appointed are naturally expected to attend political
meetings, make speeches, canvass voters, and do all the other things involved in political
activity.” Parties also use patronage for “raising campaign funds through the assessment
of public employees. ‘Two per cent clubs’ manage to squeeze large sums of money out of
politically appointed employees to help defray campaign costs. The public pay roll is thus
used in an indirect way to pay party expenses.” Maranto and Johnson (2007, p. 79) states
the claim succinctly: “Before the 1950s, U.S. political appointments were primarily to help
the incumbent party win elections as ‘spoils’ patronage.”
1
On the other hand, electoral considerations are not necessarily the primary factor affect-
ing party leaders’ decisions regarding how to distribute patronage (e.g. Sorauf, 1959; Wilson,
1961; Johnston, 1979). Many patronage jobs may be used to maintain party organizations
or be consumed as rents. Party bosses must often provide loyal lieutenants or key factional
leaders with patronage, even if this is not the most efficient allocation from a vote maxi-
mization perspective, in order to maintain their position as bosses. Surveys of patronage
recipients often find that they were not particularly active in politics either before or after
receiving their jobs (e.g. Sorauf, 1956; Johnston, 1979).
2
Furthermore, by not allocating
jobs to maximize votes, patronage could even have a negative effect on a party’s electoral
support by alienating those who do not receive jobs.
3
Pollock (1937, p. 30) writes that
1
In a similar but less critical vein, Key (1964) notes: “The patronage system may be considered, too,
as a method of financing party activity. The operation of a party organization requires the services of
many men and women... Though much of this work is performed by unpaid volunteers, their efforts are not
adequate. Indirectly, a considerable part of party expense is met by the public treasury, and the chief means
of channeling public funds to party support is through the appointment of party workers to public office.”
2
In Sorauf’s (1956) study of Centre County, Pennsylvania, only 43% claimed to have engaged in any
campaign work for the party.
3
In his study of New Haven, Johnston (1979) found that patronage was severely miss-allocated from a
vote-maximizing point of view.
2

“for every appointment which is made, perhaps a dozen disappointed persons are made to
grumble the one appointed in many cases becoming an ingrate.”
4
This paper provides evidence that patronage does or did help U.S. parties in power
retain power. To our knowledge, this is the first paper to do so. We study the U.S. states over
a one-hundred-and-ten year period, 1885-1995. Within this period there was large variation
in the timing of civil service reform across states. Illinois and Wisconsin adopted general
civil service laws in 1905, while Mississippi and Montana did not do so until 1976. The
period studied therefore includes about 20 years before 1905 and 20 years after 1976.
5
We
exploit this variation to estimate the degree to which control over patronage jobs affected a
political party’s probability of winning future elections.
In the first set of empirical analyses in this paper, we ask two simple questions: If a party
wins control of the state legislature at time t, does that party have a higher probability of
maintaining control of the legislature over the next few elections, at times t+1, t+2, etc.?
Second, and more importantly, is the probability of maintaining control of the legislature
over the next few elections even higher under a patronage system then it is after the adoption
of civil service reforms? We also study elections to statewide executive offices at t+1, t+2,
etc., in addition to control of the state legislature.
Our estimates indicate that the answer to both questions is “Yes,” and that the effects
of patronage are large. Consider a party that barely wins control of the state legislature
at time t. The probability that this party continues to control the legislature over the next
four elections is about 25 percentage points higher under a patronage system than under a
civil service system. We find a similarly large difference in the probability of winning future
4
More recently, Trounstine (n.d.) found that, conditional on running for re-election, mayors and city
council members in her sample were less likely to win in cities with large municipal workforces. As she
notes, in most cities most employees were covered by civil service law or union contracts. Restricting the
attention to cities where municipal employees were not unionized (in 1986) reversed the sign of the coefficient,
but it is statistically insignificant.
5
New York and Massachusetts adopted civil service laws very early on in 1883 and 1885 respectively
around the time the federal government adopted the Pendleton Act. West Virginia was the last state to
adopt a general civil service law, in 1989. Since these were relatively large outliers, we do not try to include
long pre-reform or post-reform periods for these states. Attempting to include a long pre-reform period for
New York and Massachusetts would be especially difficult, since it would take us into Reconstruction, and
also well into the era when most states still used party ballots rather than a secret ballot. These likely had
significant effects of their own on incumbent parties, and incorporating them would significantly complicate
the analysis.
3

elections for statewide executive offices. Overall, the evidence is strongly consistent with
the hypothesis that political parties in U.S. states were able to use patronage to increase
the probability of maintaining control of their state legislatures and also to increase the
probability of winning other statewide offices.
In the second part of the paper, we examine whether parties that control the legislature
for several years are better able to take advantage of patronage. We refer to these parties
as entrenched parties. Scholars have speculated that entrenched parties have an advantage
through the patronage system. For example, Sorauf (1959, p. 118) writes:
[J]ust as it takes money to make money, it takes political power to achieve greater
power. The party long out of office and desperately in need of new reservoirs of
strength is precisely the party that, should it suddenly find itself in office, would
be least able to use patronage for rebuilding. Weak parties lack the discipline,
the trained leadership, and the surplus of potential jobholders to use the system
to their maximum advantage.
However, there is little systematic evidence that experience controlling the government con-
fers an additional electoral advantage.
Thus, we ask another simple question: Is the higher probability of maintaining control of
the legislature over the next few elections we observe for winning control of the legislature
at time t under patronage even higher if the winning party also controlled the legislature for
several years prior to t?
Our estimates indicate that entrenched parties have an electoral advantage under the
patronage system relative to non-entrenched parties. Under a patronage system, the proba-
bility an entrenched incumbent maintains control over the subsequent elections is more than
30 percentage points higher than for a non-entrenched party. After the introduction of civil
service, we find little evidence that entrenched parties maintained their electoral advantage.
We also provide some evidence that this entrenched party advantage under patronage
may be related to entrenched parties’ ability to win “very close” elections. Prior to the
general civil service reforms, entrenched parties won about three out of four close elections.
Under civil service the entrenched parties did not have any advantage in winning these close
4

Citations
More filters
Book

Why Governments and Parties Manipulate Elections: Theory, Practice, and Implications

TL;DR: More than winning: the consequences of excessive and blatant electoral manipulation as mentioned in this paper The theory at work: evidence from case studies 7. Indirect effects of electoral manipulation: quantitative evidence 8. Conclusion.
Book

Robustness Tests for Quantitative Research

TL;DR: This highly accessible book presents the logic of robustness testing, provides an operational definition of robustity that can be applied in all quantitative research, and introduces readers to diverse types of robusts tests.
Journal ArticleDOI

Newspapers and Parties: How Advertising Revenues Created an Independent Press

TL;DR: The authors used data on 19th century American newspapers and found that newspapers were more likely to be independent from political parties in places with higher advertising revenues, and that newly created newspapers were also likely to enter the market as independents in markets with higher rates of advertising, indicating that economic development is not the only cause of the growth of an independent press.
Journal ArticleDOI

Do Voters Polarize When Radical Parties Enter Parliament

TL;DR: This paper showed that the 2002 parliamentary entrance of a radical right party led to immediate ideological polarization across the political spectrum, and that the presence of radical voices on the right has polarizing effects, illustrating how such institutional recognition and legitimization can have a farreaching impact on society.
Journal ArticleDOI

Newspapers and Parties: How Advertising Revenues Created an Independent Press

TL;DR: In this paper, economic development and higher advertising revenues tend to make media outlets independent of political groups' influence. But economic development alone is not the only reason that an independent press expands; political factors also played a role.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Randomized Experiments from Non-random Selection in U.S. House Elections

TL;DR: In this article, the authors established the relatively weak conditions under which causal inferences from a regressiondiscontinuity analysis can be as credible as those from a randomized experiment, and hence under which the validity of the RD design can be tested by examining whether or not there is a discontinuity in any pre-determined (or baseline) variables at the RD threshold.
Journal ArticleDOI

Emerging Conflicts in the Doctrines of Public Administration

TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that an examination of the administrative institutions of this country suggests that they have been organized and operated in pursuit successively of three values, here designated representativeness, neutral competence, and executive leadership.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Incumbency Advantage in U.S. Elections: An Analysis of State and Federal Offices, 1942–2000

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors compare the incumbency advantage for state and federal legislative elections over the last 60 years and find that state legislators have lower incumbency advantages than state executives and that they are similar in magnitude and have grown at the same rate as state executives.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (14)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Patronage and elections in u.s. states" ?

This paper examines whether control of patronage jobs significantly increased a political party ’ s probability of winning elections in U. S. states. The authors employ a differences-in-differencs design, exploiting the fact that there is considerable variation in the dates different states adopted civil service reforms. The authors consider several alternative hypotheses that might plausibly account for the patterns in the data, but find no evidence to support them. The authors also find evidence that an “ entrenched ” party in power for a longer time period can use patronage more effectively than a non-entrenched party. 

In section 3, the authors check the robustness of their findings against alternative explanations, such as the rising personal vote and the “ reapportionment revolution. ” This is another potential area in which the authors intend to extend their analysis. One potential concern with their analysis which the authors intend to investigate in future research is the non-random nature of when civil service reforms were enacted. Further investigation of this connection between civil service reform and the strength of party organization is another area which the authors plan to explore in future research. 

25Because there is overlap in the measure of the dependent variable across adjacent years, the authors suspect that the residuals will be serially correlated. 

Malapportionment is one potentially easy way for a party of remaining in power – it can create state legislative districts such that the areas where the supporters of the opposing party tend to live are under-represented and the areas where its supporters live are over-represented. 

One potential concern with their analysis which the authors intend to investigate in future research is the non-random nature of when civil service reforms were enacted. 

Their estimates indicate that entrenched parties have an electoral advantage under the patronage system relative to non-entrenched parties. 

A majority of the leading department heads, including the attorney general, the secretary of state, the treasurer, the auditor, and the chairman of the highway commission, are elected by popular vote. 

In section 3, the authors check the robustness of their findings against alternative explanations, such as the rising personal vote and the “reapportionment revolution.” 

As discussed in section 2, the Hatch Act may have had dampening effect on the use of patronage by prohibiting certain state employees from engaging in election-related activities. 

It is jobs and contracts for his district – especially for his supporters – that are most effective in bringing a balky legislator into line, but the governor of Mississippi has a difficult time providing either. 

The authors also examine the influence of two additional factors which may have affected the changing impact of control of the state legislature on future electoral success – the Hatch Act and collective bargaining by state employees. 

Under primaries, machine leaders would no longer have control over nominations, so that aspiring politicians would no be forced to work for the machine. 

the evidence is strongly consistent with the hypothesis that political parties in U.S. states were able to use patronage to increase the probability of maintaining control of their state legislatures and also to increase the probability of winning other statewide offices. 

The estimates imply that the probability of maintaining control of the state legislature under patronage is about 0.37 higher for the entrenched incumbent than for the non-entrenched party.