scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Institution

Georgetown University Law Center

About: Georgetown University Law Center is a based out in . It is known for research contribution in the topics: Supreme court & Public health. The organization has 585 authors who have published 2488 publications receiving 36650 citations. The organization is also known as: Georgetown Law & GULC.


Papers
More filters
Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors compared the relative economic efficiency of "nudges" and other forms of behaviorally-inspired regulation against more common policy alternatives, such as taxes, subsidies, or traditional quantity regulation.
Abstract: This Article compares for the first time the relative economic efficiency of “nudges” and other forms of behaviorally-inspired regulation against more common policy alternatives, such as taxes, subsidies, or traditional quantity regulation Environmental economists and some legal commentators have dismissed nudge-type interventions out of hand for their failure to match the revenues and informational benefits taxes can provide Similarly, writers in the law and economics tradition argue that fines are generally superior to non-pecuniary punishments Drawing on prior work in the choice-of-instruments literature, and contrary to this popular wisdom, I show that nudges may out-perform fines, other Pigouvian taxes, or subsidies in some contexts These same arguments may also imply the superiority of some traditional “command and control” regulations over their tax or subsidy alternatives I then apply these lessons to a set of contemporary policy controversies, such as New York City’s cap on beverage portion sizes, climate change, retirement savings, and charitable contributions

25 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
08 Aug 2012-JAMA
TL;DR: The court’s ruling limits federal power, while retaining state authority, supports taxation as a public health tool and warns that the mandate was tantamount to permitting government to address the diet problem by ordering everyone to buy vegetables.
Abstract: Chief Justice Roberts confounded predictions, upholding the individual mandate (that requires most individuals to pay an annual tax if they do not have health insurance by 2014) based on Congress’ taxing power. Congress’ power to “lay and collect taxes” for the common defense and welfare provides an independent source of federal authority. Although the ACA explicitly called the levy a “penalty,” the chief justice preferred a functional definition that did not rely on a label. Congress imposed a tax as the only sanction for failing to buy insurance, which is calculated and collected by the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). “That is sufficient to sustain it” under the taxing power. The tax, moreover, is not overly punitive, so individuals have a realistic choice about whether to purchase insurance or to remain uninsured. The court’s decision supports taxation as a public health tool. While affording Congress financial resources, taxes also influence health-promoting activities. Tobacco taxes, for example, discourage smoking, rather than simply raise revenue. The Commerce Power. Beyond its health policy significance, the court’s ruling limits federal power, while retaining state authority. The Constitution grants Congress limited or “enumerated” powers, while the Tenth Amendment reaffirms that “powers not delegated to the US . . . are reserved to the States.” The court said the commerce power— Congress’ constitutional authority to regulate interstate and foreign commerce—could not support the mandate. Justice Roberts reasoned that the mandate does not regulate commerce, but compels individuals to purchase a product. “Construing the Commerce Clause to permit Congress to regulate individuals precisely because they are doing nothing would open a new and potentially vast domain to congressional authority.” Reflecting the well-known broccoli analogy, Justice Roberts warned that the mandate was tantamount to permitting government to “address the diet problem by ordering everyone to buy vegetables.” Health insurance, however, is different because if healthy individuals refuse to buy it, they impose costs on society. The same cannot be said about buying vegetables or joining a gym. The mandate, moreover, does not compel commerce, but simply regulates the manner and timing of commerce. One day virtually everyone will require medical care, and someone must pay. “Free riders” reduce the insurance pool and impose costs ($62 billion in 2009) through higher taxes and insurance premiums. Thus, for only the third time since 1937, the court said Congress exceeded its commerce authority. In the previous 2 cases, the court ruled that Congress lacked the power to make gun possession within a school zone a federal offense, and to create a private civil remedy for women who had been subjected to violence. Both cases entailed purely local, noneconomic activities. Health care, however, represents 17% of the gross domestic product, with products (eg, medical records, pharmaceuticals, and insurance claims) traveling nationally and globally—clearly a regulation of commerce. The ACA’s Economic Viability. The mandate is integral to 2 pivotal, highly popular reforms: “guaranteed-issue” (insurers must cover all applicants) and “community-rating” (insurers cannot charge higher premiums based on health status). The mandate was designed to ensure the act’s economic sustainability. Without it, individuals would have an incentive to delay buying health insurance until they became ill. The critical question is whether a small tax will encourage healthy individuals to purchase health insurance. Not

25 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The Universal Declaration of Human Rights, adopted on Dec 10, 1948, established a modern human rights foundation that has become a cornerstone of global health, central to public health policies, programmes, and practices as mentioned in this paper.

25 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
05 Sep 2012-JAMA
TL;DR: Equitable distribution will require addressing the needs of underserved populations, women and people living in developing countries with high HIV incidence; meanwhile, it is necessary to consider the fair use of drugs for treatment vs. prevention and the appropriate design of new HIV prevention studies.
Abstract: ON JULY 16, 2012, EMTRICITABINE/TENOFOVIR (Truvada; Gilead Sciences) became the first drug approved by the US Food and Drug Administration (FDA) for preexposure prophylaxis (PrEP) of human immunodeficiency virus (HIV) for adults at high risk. Clinical trials have demonstrated that daily use of oral antiretroviral drugs can reduce the risk of HIV acquisition through sexual intercourse. With 50 000 new HIV infections per year in the United States and 2 million per year worldwide, PrEP could become a major component of “combination prevention” along with condoms, counseling, testing, and treatment.

25 citations


Authors

Showing all 585 results

NameH-indexPapersCitations
Lawrence O. Gostin7587923066
Michael J. Saks381555398
Chirag Shah343415056
Sara J. Rosenbaum344256907
Mark Dybul33614171
Steven C. Salop3312011330
Joost Pauwelyn321543429
Mark Tushnet312674754
Gorik Ooms291243013
Alicia Ely Yamin291222703
Julie E. Cohen28632666
James G. Hodge272252874
John H. Jackson271022919
Margaret M. Blair26754711
William W. Bratton251122037
Network Information
Related Institutions (5)
American University
13K papers, 367.2K citations

78% related

Brookings Institution
2.7K papers, 135.3K citations

78% related

London School of Economics and Political Science
35K papers, 1.4M citations

78% related

Bocconi University
8.9K papers, 344.1K citations

75% related

Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality
1.9K papers, 118K citations

75% related

Performance
Metrics
No. of papers from the Institution in previous years
YearPapers
202174
2020146
2019115
2018113
2017109
2016118