scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Beyond corporatism: A configurational theory of policy concertation

Hugh Compston
- 01 Oct 2003 - 
- Vol. 42, Iss: 6, pp 787-809
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this paper, the authors studied the political dynamics of policy concertation in terms of the varying configurations of three variables: perceived problems, the degree of shared economic understanding among the participants, and the perceived implementation capacity of the participants.
Abstract
Policy concertation (defined as making policy by means of agreements struck between government officials and representatives of employer associations and trade unions) is a major policy style in Western Europe. This article seeks to explain the political dynamics of policy concertation in terms of the varying configurations of three variables: perceived problems, the degree of shared economic understanding among the participants and the perceived implementation capacity of the participants. It is found that the incidence of broad policy concertation over the twentieth century in nine West European countries can be explained almost completely in terms of this configurational theory.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

This is an Open Access document downloaded from ORCA, Cardiff University's institutional
repository: http://orca.cf.ac.uk/3509/
This is the author’s version of a work that was submitted to / accepted for publication.
Citation for final published version:
Compston, Hugh William 2003. Beyond corporatism: a configurational theory of policy
concertation. European Journal of Political Research 42 (6) , pp. 787-809. 10.1111/1475-6765.00104
file
Publishers page: http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.00104 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1475-
6765.00104>
Please note:
Changes made as a result of publishing processes such as copy-editing, formatting and page
numbers may not be reflected in this version. For the definitive version of this publication, please
refer to the published source. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite
this paper.
This version is being made available in accordance with publisher policies. See
http://orca.cf.ac.uk/policies.html for usage policies. Copyright and moral rights for publications
made available in ORCA are retained by the copyright holders.

BEYOND CORPORATISM
A CONFIGURATIONAL THEORY OF POLICY CONCERTATION
Hugh Compston
School of European Studies, Cardiff University, UK
Post-print: article as accepted for publication in
European Journal of Political Research, 42, 2003: 809-831
ABSTRACT
Policy concertation, defined as making policy by means of agreements struck between government
officials and representatives of employer associations and trade unions, is a major policy style in
Western Europe. This article seeks to explain the political dynamics of policy concertation in terms
of the varying configurations of three variables: perceived problems, the degree of shared economic
understanding among the participants, and the perceived implementation capacity of the
participants. It is found that the incidence of broad policy concertation over the 20th century in nine
West European countries can be almost completely explained in terms of this configurational theory.
Key words: policy, concertation, corporatism, Europe, employers, trade unions

1
INTRODUCTION
Although the idea of employers and unions participating in the making of public policy sounds
strange to British ears, elsewhere in Western Europe public policy is often made by means of
agreements struck between government officials and representatives of employer associations and
trade unions. This practice, which can be termed ‘policy concertation’ to distinguish it from the
more pluralist policy-making characteristic of Britain and other Anglo-Saxon countries, is
significant because it affects the content of public policy and therefore the shape of the society we
live in. Because decisions are taken by agreement, each participant has a power of veto and is
therefore guaranteed influence over the decision. This rules out policy decisions that are
unacceptable to employers or trade unions. It also leads governments to introduce policies that they
would not otherwise have introduced, in exchange for concessions from employers and unions. In
certain cases, the political exchange of policy concertation may render feasible policy options not
previously open to the government, such as expansionary economic policies dependent on wage
restraint.
Policy concertation in Western Europe during the 1990s included social pacts, agreements struck
within the regular state policy-making apparatus between representatives of business, labour and the
state, and the implementation by the state of bipartite employer-union agreements. It is most
common in the fields of employment and social policy, but in some countries encompasses
significant areas of economic policy as well. This broad policy concertation has been associated
historically with countries such as Austria, with its Social Partnership, as well as with the
Netherlands and Sweden, but the breadth of policy areas covered by policy concertation also varies
over time: during the 1990s broad policy concertation was still characteristic of Austria, for
example, but had ceased to exist in the Netherlands and Sweden while becoming established in
Ireland and Italy (Table 1).
Why does the range of public policy codetermined by policy concertation vary between countries
and over time? The purpose of this article is to answer this question.
1
My starting point is the limited success of theories that use a distinctive corporatist logic to explain
the incidence of broad policy concertation in recent years. Not all corporatist theories are devoted to
explaining policy concertation, of course. Some seek to explain phenomena such as economic policy
and economic outcomes (eg Cameron 1984, Crepaz 1992, Woldendorp 1997), while others focus on
explicating corporatism as a state of affairs (eg Lijphart and Crepaz 1991, Keman and Pennings
1995, Siaroff 1999). And those theories that are designed to explain policy concertation often use
different terms to refer to it, including the term ‘corporatism’ itself (eg Lehmbruch 1979,
Woldendorp 1997).

2
Table 1. Policy Concertation in Western Europe, 1990-1997
Country
Policy areas covered
Wide-concertation countries with frequent concertation
Austria
Social policy, fiscal policy, monetary policy, investment policy, industrial policy,
social welfare, labour law, job-creation and training, employment, EU-issues
Wide-concertation countries with sporadic concertation
Ireland
Overall macro-economic policy strategy, social welfare, government spending in
general, employment policy including active labour market policy, regional policy
Medium-concertation countries with sporadic concertation
Italy
Taxation, expenditure (especially pensions), labour law
Narrow-concertation countries with frequent concertation
Netherlands
Social security, employment policy
Sweden
Many sectors until 1992, then restricted to labour market policy and pensions
Germany
Social insurance, labour law, health, reconstruction of the East
Narrow-concertation countries with sporadic concertation
Spain
Employment law and social security
France
Employment law and social security
Non-concertation countries
Britain
None
Source: Berger and Compston 2002, political country chapters.
Arguably the most influential theory of policy concertation that does utilise a corporatist logic of
explanation starts with the proposition that the existence of corporatist systems of interest
intermediation in Schmitter’s original sense (Schmitter 1979: 13) means that the organisations
involved can no longer externalise the economic costs of their actions. If a trade union in a single
industry makes excessive wage claims, it may be possible for employers in that industry to pass
these on in the form of higher prices to the rest of society, but if a union movement that
encompasses most of a nation’s workforce makes excessive wage claims, the resultant price rises hit
everyone, including union members. For this reason, encompassing union movements are expected
to be more open to negotiating wage restraint than smaller or divided movements, which encourages
governments to enter policy concertation with the intent of offering policy concessions in exchange

3
for wage restraint (Calmfors 1993, Olson 1982). Corporatism is also expected to facilitate
negotiations by limiting the number of participants and by giving to leaders of trade union
confederations and employer peak associations the ability to make the binding commitments on
behalf of their members that are essential if political exchange is to take place on a continuing basis
(Lehmbruch 1979: 167-168, Slomp 1992: 163, Crouch 1993: 54-55, 289).
The problem with this model is that it fails to account for the incidence of broad policy concertation
in Western Europe in the 1990s. Although it can explain the persistence of broad policy concertation
in Austria, where the compulsory Chamber system is as close to an ideal-type corporatist system as
exists in Western Europe, it cannot explain its rise in Ireland, where the distribution of power within
employer associations and trade unions is relatively decentralised, or its resurgence in Italy, where
employer associations and trade union confederations are institutionally divided.
There are a number of other theories of policy concertation that utilise conceptions of corporatism as
explanatory variables, but these generally go beyond the corporatist logic of explanation to include
other explanatory variables as well. A number of such variables have been cited in the political
economy literature. These include the postwar emergence of a willingness on the part of
governments to trade policy concessions for certain commitments by employers and/or trade unions
due to the postwar extension of the role of government in managing the economy, labour party
participation in government, economic openness, consociationalism, economic consensus,
egalitarian political cultures, degree of societal support, the relationship of organised groups to
modernisation in previous centuries, and the extensive institutionalisation of contacts between
employers, trade unions and the state (for a review of these theories see Compston 1998, 2002).
Rather than criticising these theories, a number of which have considerable explanatory power, what
I wish to do here is to offer a new theory of policy concertation that also goes beyond the logic of
corporatism by utilising different independent variables and a different logic of explanation, a theory
that provides a parsimonious explanation of the incidence of broad policy concertation since 1945
that is at least as compelling as the accounts offered by existing theories. This configurational theory
explains broad policy concertation in terms of the changing configurations of values of just three
variables: the nature of contemporary problems as perceived by the government; the degree of pre-
existent shared understanding of the aims and mechanisms of economic policy among governments,
employers and unions; and expectations about the likelihood that the prospective participants will
implement their sides of any agreements reached.
The first part of the article is devoted to describing this configurational theory and how it works. The
second part uses the findings of a major international study of policy concertation to illustrate how
the political dynamics of broad policy concertation in Western Europe since 1945 can be almost
completely accounted for in terms of the shifting configurations of values of the three explanatory
variables.
A CONFIGURATIONAL MODEL OF POLICY CONCERTATION
The model of policy concertation set out below is inspired by John Kingdon’s theory of agenda-
setting, in which items are seen as coming up for decision when simultaneously a compelling
problem is recognised, a solution in the form of a technically and politically feasible policy proposal
is available, political change makes politicians receptive, and potential constraints are not too severe
(Kingdon 1995). Applying Kingdon’s approach to a different dependent variable results in a
different theory, but the logic is the same in that both posit that the value of the dependent variable
is determined by the coincidence in time of specific configurations of events and conditions.

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Next-Generation Innovation Policy and Grand Challenges

TL;DR: In this article, the authors explore transformative ways to address Grand Challenges, while locating them in a broader diagnosis of ongoing changes, and present building blocks for a next generation of innovation policies, and discuss the opportunities offered by new constellations of actors and their concertation.
Journal ArticleDOI

EMU and Labor Market Institutions in Europe: The Rise and Fall of National Social Pacts

TL;DR: The authors argue that the different forms of institutional innovation in wage setting found in the EU depended on the combination of the character of external pressures and preexisting protoinstitutional structures in the labor market.
Journal ArticleDOI

Defending the organisation, not the members: Unions and the reform of job security legislation in Western Europe

TL;DR: In this paper, it is argued that unions' institutional power resources are the crucial variable explaining the two-tier labour markets in Europe, and that unions will assent to labour market reforms, but only to those that do not fundamentally threaten their organisational interests.

Decentralization, Interactive Governance and Income Inequality: A Comparative Study

TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that decentralization leads to higher income inequality and that interactive governance is associated with lower income inequality, and that more shared fiscal rule between the subnational regions and the central government is significantly associated with less income inequality.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Still the Century of Corporatism

TL;DR: For instance, Manoilesco's confident prediction could easily be dismissed as yet another example of the ideological bias, wishful thinking and overinflated rhetoric of the thirties, an evenementielle response to a peculiar environment and period.
Journal ArticleDOI

Corporatism in 24 industrial democracies: Meaning and measurement

TL;DR: In this paper, a comparative analysis of 24 long-term industrial democracies in terms of the corporatism scores given by 23 different scholarly analyses is presented, and an alternative, more focused summary measure of economic integration is proposed.
Journal ArticleDOI

Corporatism and Consensus Democracy in Eighteen Countries: Conceptual and Empirical Linkages

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors place the form of interest representation and the involvement of interest groups in policy formation known as corporatism in a broader political context: is corporatism systematically linked with other democratic institutions and processes?
Book ChapterDOI

Liberal Corporatism and Party Government

TL;DR: The progress of corporatist ideas since the late nineteenth century and the advent of authoritarian "corporatist" regimes in the twentieth century have been strongly fostered by critiques of parliamentary and party government as discussed by the authors.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "A configurational theory of policy concertation" ?

This article seeks to explain the political dynamics of policy concertation in terms of the varying configurations of three variables: perceived problems, the degree of shared economic understanding among the participants, and the perceived implementation capacity of the participants. 

Further work is obviously needed if a theory with one hundred per cent explanatory success is to be constructed, but in the meantime the substantial explanatory success of the configurational theory means that it constitutes a powerful device for understanding the causal dynamics of policy concertation. 

The establishment in the Netherlands of a set of corporatist institutions designed in part as forums for policy concertation was largely motivated by the felt urgency of postwar reconstruction and preceded by growing shared economic understanding. 

In addition, the new government’s application of Keynesian techniques in the mid-1960s was followed by a resurgence of economic growth, reducing the incentive to engage in policy concertation. 

In addition, when the Federal Republic was established in 1949 new approaches were already being tried to tackle Germany’s serious economic problems, namely the currency reform of 1948 and ‘social market’ ideas. 

The lack of postwar broad policy concertation in Britain during this period, despite considerable agreement on economic policy and the precedent of effective policy concertation during the war, can be explained in terms of the theory by the fact that expectations of implementation were undermined by the inability of the peak employer and union confederations to guarantee the compliance of their constituent organisations with any agreements reached at national level. 

There was just one country in which no policy concertation of any sort occurred: Britain, where all forms of policy concertation were extinguished by the vehemently anti-union Conservative government of 1979-1997. 

In Ireland, economic problems had persisted throughout the postwar period but it was not until the economic views of governments, employers and trade unions converged somewhat, and centralised collective bargaining simplified the problem of implementing wage agreements after 1970, that policy concertation emerged when the government began to facilitate annual wage agreements by offering budgetary concessions. 

If employers or governments do not, then not only would it be difficult to obtain the wage restraint often desired by governments and employers in exchange for policy concessions, since the coordination of wage rises via collective bargaining would be rendered impossible, but in addition the degree of hostility and distrust between employers and unions would be likely to prevent agreement anyway. 

The persistence of periodic broad policy concertation during this period has been accompanied by a widespread view that Italy’s substantial progress in tackling its economic problems in recent years can be at least in part attributed to the social pacts of 1992, 1993 and 1995. 

Although it can explain the persistence of broad policy concertation in Austria, where the compulsory Chamber system is as close to an ideal-type corporatist system as exists in Western Europe, it cannot explain its rise in Ireland, where the distribution of power within employer associations and trade unions is relatively decentralised, or its resurgence in Italy, where employer associations and trade union confederations are institutionally divided. 

Rather than criticising these theories, a number of which have considerable explanatory power, what The authorwish to do here is to offer a new theory of policy concertation that also goes beyond the logic of corporatism by utilising different independent variables and a different logic of explanation, a theory that provides a parsimonious explanation of the incidence of broad policy concertation since 1945 that is at least as compelling as the accounts offered by existing theories. 

In Germany, on the other hand, where policy concertation had been restricted to certain areas of social insurance, labour law and health, the severe economic and social problems created by reunification led to short-term broad policy concertation in the form of the 1993 Solidarity Pact.