scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Liquidity, Moral Hazard and Inter-Bank Market Collapse

TLDR
In this article, the authors proposed a framework to analyze the functioning of the interbank liquidity market and the occurrence of liquidity crises, which relies on three key assumptions: (i) liquidity provisioning is not verifiable -it cannot be contracted upon-, (ii) banks face moral hazard when confronted with liquidity shocks-unobservable effort can help overcome the shock, and (iii) liquidity shocks are private information - they cannot be diversified away.
Abstract
This paper proposes a framework to analyze the functioning of the inter-bank liquidity market and the occurrence of liquidity crises. The model relies on three key assumptions: (i) liquidity provisioning is not verifiable -it cannot be contracted upon-, (ii) banks face moral hazard when confronted with liquidity shocks-unobservable effort can help overcome the shock-, (iii) liquidity shocks are private information - they cannot be diversified away-. Under these assumptions, the equilibrium risk-adjusted return on liquidity provisioning increases with the aggregate equilibrium volume of ex ante liquidity provision. As a consequence, banks may provision too little liquidity compared with the social optimum. Within this framework we derive two main results. First inter-bank market collapse is an equilibrium. Second such an equilibrium is more likely when (i) the individual probability of the liquidity shock is lower, (ii) ex ante competition between banks on illiquid long term assets is larger.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and
Interbank Market Collapse
Enisse Kharroubi
a
and Edouard Vidon
a,b
a
Banque de France
b
International Monetary Fund
This paper proposes a framework to analyze the functioning
of the interbank liquidity market and the occurrence of liquid-
ity crises. The model relies on three key assumptions: (i) ex
ante investment in liquid assets is not verifiable—it cannot be
contracted upon, (ii) banks face moral hazard when confronted
with liquidity shocks—unobservable effort can help overcome
the shock, and (iii) liquidity shocks are private information—
they cannot be diversified away. Under these assumptions,
the aggregate volume of capital invested in liquid assets is
shown to exert a positive externality on individual decisions
to hoard liquid assets. Due to this property, the collapse of
the interbank market for liquidity is an equilibrium. More-
over, such an equilibrium is more likely when the individual
probability of the liquidity shock is lower. Banks may there-
fore provision too few liquid assets compared with the social
optimum.
JEL Codes: D53, D82, D86.
We thank Nuno Cassola, Edouard Challe, Denis Gromb, Arvind Krish-
namurthy, Henri Pag`es, Jean-Charles Rochet, Rafael Repullo, Tano Santos,
Jean Tirole, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions.
All remaining errors are ours. A previous version of the paper was circulated
under the title “Increasing Returns in Inter-Bank Liquidity Market.” The views
expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the
Banque de France, the Eurosystem, or the International Monetary Fund, its
executive board, or its management. Corresponding author: Enisse Kharroubi.
Address: Banque de France. 49-1374. 1, rue de la Vrilli`ere. 75049 Paris cedex 01.
E-mail: enisse.kharroubi@banque-france.fr. Tel: + 33 1 42 92 47 39. Fax: + 33 1
42 92 49 50.
51

52 International Journal of Central Banking December 2009
1. Introduction
The financial market turmoil that has been under way since the sum-
mer of 2007 hit the core of the global financial system, the interbank
market for liquidity. While this paper does not endeavor to account
for all the features of the recent crisis, be it hard evidence or casual
stories about the motivations of market players, it argues that a
proper modeling of the collapse in the market for liquidity involves
a close look at incentives to provision/hoard liquidity and moral haz-
ard mechanisms in the interbank market. In addition, it makes sense
to do so in a framework where banks can actually fail and default
on their borrowing. Both of these assumptions are strongly vindi-
cated by salient features of the recent crisis. Many observers have
argued that securitization may have provided the wrong incentives
regarding the monitoring of underlying asset quality, in a clear-cut
case of moral hazard. In addition, recent developments have shown
that bank failure scenarios are only too realistic.
We investigate the possible role of insufficient ex ante liquidity
provision in paving the way to an interbank market collapse. We
thus highlight the benefits of situations where banks set aside large
amounts of liquid assets in order to better deal with shocks affecting
their illiquid investments. By liquidity provisions, we mean specifi-
cally holdings of assets that can be used to safely transfer wealth over
a short period of time. This may be seen as a form of “balance-sheet
liquidity.” In practice, such liquid holdings could be remunerated
reserves held at the central bank, or short-term Treasury securities.
1
Indeed, the secular decline in the share of liquid assets on banks’ bal-
ance sheets is a striking stylized fact that has been underscored by
Goodhart (2008) as a troubling feature of risk management. A situ-
ation where market and funding liquidity appeared to be high may
thus have hidden vulnerabilities stemming from limited holdings of
liquid assets.
Against such a background, this paper shows that across equilib-
ria, the risk-adjusted return on liquid assets can be increasing with
1
We do not model a risk-free asset market as such; however, we will simply
assume that a technology providing a risk-free rate of return is available as an
alternative to illiquid investments on the one hand, and to interbank lending on
the other hand.

Vol. 5 No. 4 Liquidity, Moral Hazard 53
the aggregate volume of such assets in the economy. When a bank
faces a liquidity shock, it needs to reinvest in its impaired assets.
Moreover, success in reinvestment depends on the effort the bank
undertakes. When it has provisioned a large volume of liquidity ex
ante, reinvestment is mostly financed through internal funds. Hence,
the distressed bank pays particular attention to improving the prob-
ability that reinvestment succeeds. Consequently, the moral hazard
problem is mitigated and the distressed bank benefits from a large
capacity to borrow liquidity on the interbank market. This tends
to raise the demand for liquidity and hence the price of liquidity,
which in turn raises incentives to provision liquid assets ex ante. As
a result, both the risk-adjusted return on liquidity provisioning and
the total volume of liquidity in the economy are large.
By contrast, with low ex ante liquidity provision, the argument is
reversed: the moral hazard problem is amplified through the afore-
mentioned channel—reinvestment is mostly financed through exter-
nal funds. Intact lending banks then impose a tight constraint on
the volume of liquidity distressed banks can borrow on the inter-
bank market so as to restore their incentives to deliver effort. This,
however, reduces the demand for liquidity and drives down the price
of liquidity, which in turn depresses banks’ incentives to provision
liquidity ex ante. Consequently, the risk-adjusted return on liquid-
ity provisioning and the total volume of liquidity in the economy are
low. The two polar cases of high and low liquidity provisions can
therefore both be equilibrium outcomes.
Turning to comparative statics, the credit-rationing equilibrium
happens to be more likely when the liquidity shock is less likely. We
call this property the curse of good times. When the probability of
facing the liquidity shock is low, banks reduce their liquidity holdings
because they are less likely to need these liquid assets for reinvest-
ment. This tightens the moral-hazard-induced liquidity constraint,
reducing the demand for liquid assets and thereby the return on
liquid assets on the interbank market, which in turn reduces incen-
tives to provision liquidity ex ante. Conversely, the equilibrium with
large liquidity provision and high risk-adjusted return is more likely
when the liquidity shock is more likely, a property we call the virtue
of bad times. When the probability of facing the liquidity shock
is high, banks raise their liquidity holdings because they are more
likely to need these provisions for reinvestment. This relaxes the

54 International Journal of Central Banking December 2009
moral-hazard-induced liquidity constraint, raising the demand for
liquidity and thereby the price of liquidity on the interbank market,
which in turn raises incentives to provision liquidity ex ante. Hence,
when the probability of the liquidity shock is intermediate, multiple
equilibria emerge: large (resp. low) aggregate investment in liquid
assets tends to raise (resp. reduce) the return on liquid assets and
thereby raise (resp. reduce) individual incentives to invest in liquid
assets.
Finally, the paper investigates how policy can prevent or dampen
a collapse of the market for liquidity. The main result is that policies
aimed at tackling the collapse of the interbank market ex post—i.e.,
after the collapse has happened—are unlikely to reach their goal. In
particular, liquidity injections as well as interest rate cuts cannot
help distressed banks overcome their liquidity shocks. By contrast,
ex ante policies, especially those that modify the relative return of
liquid assets compared with illiquid assets, can be successful in pre-
venting a collapse of the interbank market. In other words, monetary
policy, by setting short-term interest rates which provide incentives
to invest in liquid assets, can be helpful in reducing the occurrence
of liquidity crises. Regulatory policies requiring liquidity provision
can also be useful.
The model in this paper builds on the standard literature on
moral hazard and liquidity crisis. The demand for liquidity is mod-
eled in a basic, standard fashion, similar to that of Holmstr¨om and
Tirole (1998). Agents (in our case, banks) with long-term assets
face stochastic liquidity shocks which trigger a reinvestment need
and a moral hazard problem: success in reinvestment depends on
unobservable effort by banks.
2
We, however, depart from this sem-
inal paper in an important way, by assuming that idiosyncratic
liquidity shocks cannot be diversified away: this opens the door
to an interbank market where liquidity can be reallocated interim.
Because of this feature, our framework is closely related to the
2
The main alternative modeling of liquidity is based on the Diamond and
Dybvig (1983) approach—enriched by Diamond and Rajan (2001)—in which
banks with illiquid assets supply liquidity to consumers through liquid deposits
(funding liquidity). While this approach can account for bank runs that have
taken place during the current financial crisis, the Holmstr¨om and Tirole (1998)
approach, focused on market liquidity, seems more relevant given the particular
initial circumstances of the crisis.

Vol. 5 No. 4 Liquidity, Moral Hazard 55
model of liquidity demand developed by Caballero and Krishna-
murthy in a series of papers (in particular, Caballero and Krish-
namurthy 2004) dealing with access to international financing. Our
model shares their features that (i) idiosyncratic shocks cannot be
written into insurance contracts, generating the need for domestic
financial transactions, and (ii) borrowers cannot transfer the full
surplus generated by reinvestment resources. Likewise, we therefore
have situations where private decisions are biased against hoarding
liquidity.
Our paper is connected to the literature on interbank markets, as
a mechanism for managing, and potentially eliminating, risks stem-
ming from idiosyncratic liquidity shocks. Bhattacharya and Gale
(1987) in particular studied the case where neither banks’ invest-
ments in the illiquid technology nor liquidity shocks are observ-
able. In their framework, banks have an incentive to underprovision
liquidity ex ante and free-ride the common pool of liquidity. Rochet
and Tirole (1996) adapted the Holmstr¨om-Tirole framework to the
interbank market in order to study systemic risk and “too-big-to-
fail” policy. The existence of interbank market imperfections has
been established empirically by Kashyap and Stein (2000), which
showed the role of liquidity positions, the so-called “liquidity effect.”
Building on such evidence, Freixas and Jorge (2008) analyzed the
functioning of the interbank market in order to show the conse-
quences of its imperfections for monetary policy. In particular, they
established the relevance of heterogeneity in banks’ liquid asset hold-
ings for policy transmission.
Our work is also related to recent work on liquidity crises. A
recent strand of literature has explored the propagation of crises
through banks’ balance sheets, while treating the level of liquidity
held by banks as endogenous. This approach builds on Allen and
Gale’s (1998) analysis of distressed liquidation of risky assets, to
explore the mechanism whereby anticipation of fire-sale pricing of
such assets determines banks’ ex ante portfolio allocation. Allen and
Gale (2004) as well as Acharya, Shin, and Yorulmazer (2007, 2009)
have concentrated on this interaction between equilibrium liquid-
ity and endogenously determined fire sales. In particular, Acharya,
Shin, and Yorulmazer (2007) showed that banks’ holdings of liquid-
ity may be too low or too high compared with the social optimum,
depending on the pledgeability of their assets and the possibility to

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Financial Constraints, Competition and Hedging in Industry Equilibrium

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors analyze the hedging decisions of firms, within an equilibrium setting that allows them to examine how a firm's hedging choice depends on the hedge choices of its competitors.
Posted Content

Some evidence on the uniqueness of bank loans

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present evidence that banks provide some special service with their lending activity that is not available from other lenders, and they find evidence that bank borrowers, not CD holders, bear the cost of reserve requirements on CDs.
Posted Content

Education, Market Rigidities and Growth

TL;DR: In this article, the authors investigated the effects of education level, product market rigidities and employment protection legislation on growth in countries close to the technological frontier, and found that education and rigidities are significantly related to TFP growth.
Journal ArticleDOI

Flight to Liquidity and the Great Recession

TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that countercyclical liquidity hoarding by financial intermediaries may strongly amplify business cycles and develop a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model in which banks operate subject to financial frictions and idiosyncratic funding liquidity risk in their intermediation activity.
Posted ContentDOI

Ambiguity and Interbank Market Participation: Relationship and Transactional Banking

Reina Renard
TL;DR: In this article, the authors identify the conditions that have helped lead to an improvement in IBM liquidity via establishing a relationship, which can stimulate lenders to participate in the IBM market since relationships allow lenders to be more confident in their assessment about the borrower's quality.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a struggling attempt to give structure to the statement: "Business in under-developed countries is difficult"; in particular, a structure is given for determining the economic costs of dishonesty.
Journal ArticleDOI

Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity

TL;DR: The authors showed that bank deposit contracts can provide allocations superior to those of exchange markets, offering an explanation of how banks subject to runs can attract deposits, and showed that there are circumstances when government provision of deposit insurance can produce superior contracts.
Journal ArticleDOI

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and The Real Sector

TL;DR: In this article, an incentive model of financial intermediation in which firms as well as intermediaries are capital constrained is studied, and how the distribution of wealth across firms, intermediaries, and uninformed investors affects investment, interest rates, and the intensity of monitoring.
Book

Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises

TL;DR: In this article, the authors discuss the history of the financial crisis and its role in economic and monetary instability, including speculative manias, economic booms, and international contagion, and the international lender of last resort.
Journal ArticleDOI

What Do a Million Observations on Banks Say about the Transmission of Monetary Policy

TL;DR: The authors found that the impact of monetary policy on lending is stronger for banks with less liquid balance sheets, i.e., banks with lower ratios of securities to assets, and that this pattern is largely attributable to the smaller banks, those in the bottom 95 percent of the size distribution.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Liquidity, moral hazard, and interbank market collapse" ?

This paper proposes a framework to analyze the functioning of the interbank liquidity market and the occurrence of liquidity crises. 

These are possible research avenues for future work. However, since by assumption the authors have eh ≥ 1 − q, this condition can not be satisfied. There may be two types of such equilibria. Having determined banks ’ date 1 decisions, the authors can turn to banks ’ date 0 problem, which writes as max l ( 1 − q ) [ ( 1 − l ) R + [ ( 1 − l ) β + l ] max { ehr ; 1 } ] + qehr R [ 1 − ψ ] r − ψR ( l + ρα ( 1 − l ) ).