scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

The Structure of Inequality and the Politics of Redistribution

Noam Lupu
- 01 May 2011 - 
- Vol. 105, Iss: 02, pp 316-336
TLDR
The authors argue that inequality matters for redistributive politics in advanced capitalist societies, but it is the structure of inequality, not the level of inequality that matters, and they test this proposition with data from 15 to 18 advanced democracies and find that both redistribution and none-lderly social spending increase as the dispersion of earnings in the upper half of the distribution increases relative to the distribution in the lower half.
Abstract
Against the current consensus among comparative political economists, we argue that inequality matters for redistributive politics in advanced capitalist societies, but it is the structure of inequality, not the level of inequality, that matters. Our theory posits that middle-income voters will be inclined to ally with low-income voters and support redistributive policies when the distance between the middle and the poor is small relative to the distance between the middle and the rich. We test this proposition with data from 15 to 18 advanced democracies and find that both redistribution and nonelderly social spending increase as the dispersion of earnings in the upper half of the distribution increases relative to the dispersion of earnings in the lower half of the distribution. In addition, we present survey evidence on preferences for redistribution among middle-income voters that is consistent with our theory and regression results indicating that the left parties are more likely to participate in government when the structure of inequality is characterized by skew.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Article
Reference
The Structure of Inequality and the Politics of Redistribution
LUPU, Noam, PONTUSSON, Harry Jonas
Abstract
Against the current consensus among comparative political economists, we argue that
inequality matters for redistributive politics in advanced capitalist societies, but it is the
structure of inequality, not the level of inequality, that matters. Our theory posits that
middle-income voters will be inclined to ally with low-income voters and support redistributive
policies when the distance between the middle and the poor is small relative to the distance
between the middle and the rich. We test this proposition with data from 15 to 18 advanced
democracies and find that both redistribution and nonelderly social spending increase as the
dispersion of earnings in the upper half of the distribution increases relative to the dispersion
of earnings in the lower half of the distribution. In addition, we present survey evidence on
preferences for redistribution among middle-income voters that is consistent with our theory
and regression results indicating that the left parties are more likely to participate in
government when the structure of inequality is characterized by skew.
LUPU, Noam, PONTUSSON, Harry Jonas. The Structure of Inequality and the Politics of
Redistribution. The American political science review, 2011, vol. 105, no. 02, p. 316-336
DOI : 10.1017/S0003055411000128
Available at:
http://archive-ouverte.unige.ch/unige:40999
Disclaimer: layout of this document may differ from the published version.
1 / 1

psr1100012 xxx (xxx) April 25, 2011 14:49
American Political Science Review Vol. 105, No. 2 May 2011
doi:10.1017/S0003055411000128
The Structure of Inequality and the Politics of Redistribution
NOAM LUPU Princeton University
JONAS PONTUSSON Universit
´
edeGen
`
eve
A
gainst the current consensus among comparative political economists, we argue that inequality
matters for redistributive politics in advanced capitalist societies, but it is the structure of in-
equality, not the level of inequality, that matters. Our theory posits that middle-income voters
will be inclined to ally with low-income voters and support redistributive policies when the distance
between the middle and the poor is small relative to the distance between the middle and the rich. We
test this proposition with data from 15 to 18 advanced democracies and find that both redistribution and
nonelderly social spending increase as the dispersion of earnings in the upper half of the distribution
increases relative to the dispersion of earnings in the lower half of the distribution. In addition, we present
survey evidence on preferences for redistribution among middle-income voters that is consistent with our
theory and regression results indicating that the left parties are more likely to participate in government
when the structure of inequality is characterized by skew.
T
he recent growth of empirical scholarship on the
politics of redistribution in advanced capitalist
societies is impressive. Taking the canonical me-
dian voter model associated with Romer (1975) and
Meltzer and Richard (1981) as the point of departure,
much of this research asks, “Does more inequality
lead to more redistribution?” Although Kenworthy
and Pontusson (2005) and Milanovic (2000) show that
patterns of within-country variation broadly conform
to the core prediction of the Romer-Meltzer-Richard
(RMR) model, others point out that the cross-national
association between income inequality and redistribu-
tion among Organisation of Economic Co-operation
and Development (OECD) countries is in fact the op-
posite of what the canonical model seems to predict:
Governments in less egalitarian countries tend to en-
gage in less redistribution (e.g., Alesina and Glaeser
2004, 57–60). Perhaps because of the difficulty of recon-
ciling within- and cross-country evidence, the current
consensus seems to be that inequality does not matter
for the politics of redistribution, at least not in any
direct and particularly significant way. Instead, recent
studies emphasize the causal role of a range of other
Noam Lupu is a Ph.D. candidate, Department of Politics, Prince-
ton University, 130 Corwin Hall, Princeton, NJ 08544 (nlupu@
princeton.edu).
Jonas Pontusson is Professor of Comparative Politics,
D
´
epartement de science politique, Universit
´
edeGen
`
eve, 40, Boule-
vard du Pont d’Arve, 1211 Gen
`
eve 4, Switzerland (Jonas.Pontusson@
unige.ch).
Previous versions of this article were presented in seminars and
workshops at Harvard, Oxford, Princeton, Stanford, and the Univer-
sities of Toronto and Geneva, as well as the 2010 Annual Meetings
of the American Political Science Association and Midwest Polit-
ical Science Association. We are grateful to the many individuals
who asked difficult questions and made useful suggestions in these
venues. For detailed comments, we are indebted to Pablo Beramendi,
Michael Donnelly, Patrick Emmenegger, John Ferejohn, John
Huber, Kosuke Imai, Torben Iversen, Nolan McCarty, Gwyneth
McClendon, Daniel Oesch, Damian Raess, David Rueda, David
Soskice, and K
˚
are Vernby, in addition to the anonymous review-
ers and APSR editors. We also thank Rafaela Dancygier and Lane
Kenworthy for sharing their data. Replication data and do-file are
available on Lupu’s Web site. All unreported empirical analyses are
available from the authors on request.
factors: electoral rules (Persson, Roland, and Tabellini
2007; Persson and Tabellini 2003), government parti-
sanship (Bradley et al. 2003; Iversen and Soskice 2006),
national skill profiles (Iversen 2005; Iversen and Sos-
kice 2001), racial and ethnic diversity (Alesina and
Glaeser 2004), and religiosity (Scheve and Stasavage
2006).
We build on recent studies that treat racial and ethnic
diversity as an obstacle to redistributive politics. The
core idea of this literature is that social affinity is a
critical determinant of preferences for redistribution;
when racial or ethnic minorities comprise a significant
proportion of the poor, members of the majority group
are less likely to support redistributive policies. We
argue that social affinity should be conceived more
broadly and that the common circumstances and so-
cial networks associated with income are important
constitutive elements of social affinity, in addition to
racial or ethnic group membership. Inspired by Kristov,
Lindert, and McClelland (1992), this perspective sug-
gests that what matters to the politics of redistribution
is not the level of inequality, but rather the structure
of inequality.
1
Assuming that the support of middle-
income voters is critical to the implementation of re-
distributive policies, our theoretical framework boils
down to the following proposition: In the absence of
cross-cutting ethnic cleavages, middle-income voters
will empathize with the poor and support redistributive
policies when the income distance between the middle
and the poor is small relative to the income distance
between the middle and the affluenta condition
we refer to as skew.
2
1
Incorporating the role of pressure groups, Kristov, Lindert, and
McClelland’s (1992) theory of redistributive politics is quite different
from ours. Our indebtedness to these authors concerns the basic
idea that the structure of income inequality matters to redistributive
politics.
2
In a similar vein, Wilensky (1975, 57) asserts that “the more social
distance between the middle mass and the poor, the greater the
resistance to spending that appears to favor the poor.” Unlike Wilen-
sky, we emphasize income as the basis for social distance and also
consider the distance between the middle and the affluent. On both
counts, our core argument resonates with Acemoglu and Robinson’s
(2006) discussion of the role of the middle class in democratization.
1

psr1100012 xxx (xxx) April 25, 2011 14:49
Inequality and Redistribution May 2011
Our empirical analysis provides an initial test of the
social affinity hypothesis by estimating several models
of redistribution and social spending with data from 15
to 18 OECD countries over the period 1969 to 2004.
Controlling for factors that previous studies identify
as determinants of redistribution, and using measures
of inequality based on gross earnings, we show that
redistribution increases with dispersion of the upper
half of the earnings distribution and with compression
of the lower half of the earnings distribution. We go on
to probe the causal mechanisms behind these results
in two steps. We first present descriptive survey evi-
dence in support of our claims that (1) redistributive
policy outcomes correspond to the policy preferences
of middle-income voters, and (2) the structure of in-
equality helps explain why the preferences of middle-
income voters vary across countries and over time. The
second step explores the role of government partisan-
ship as an intervening variable, connecting demand for
redistribution to redistributive policy outcomes. Our
evidence on this score is far from definitive, but it
suggests that left-leaning governments are more likely
to redistribute income than right-leaning governments
and that governments are more likely to be left-leaning
when the structure of inequality is skewed.
We agree with Brooks and Manza (2007) that pub-
lic opinion matters more than the comparative wel-
fare state literature has generally recognized (cf. also
Kenworthy and McCall 2008). However, our approach
differs from theirs in two important respects. First, we
focus on the preferences of a particular and, arguably,
pivotal segment of the publicmiddle-income voters.
Second, we aspire not only to show that the preferences
of middle-income voters matter to policy outcomes, but
also to explain why the preferences of middle-income
voters vary across countries and over time. Our account
of why these preferences vary stands in sharp contrast
to the social rivalry hypothesis articulated by Corneo
and Gr
¨
uner (2002) and implicitly embraced by Shayo
(2009).
SOCIAL AFFINITY AND POLITICAL
COALITIONS
The model of redistributive politics proposed by
Romer (1975) and developed by Meltzer and Richard
(1981) does not provide an adequate explanation of
variation in the extent of government redistribution
across OECD countries. As commonly noted (e.g., Mc-
Carty and Pontusson 2009, 669–72), the limitations of
the RMR model may be attributed to its assumptions
about either the demand for or supply of redistribution
(or both). We focus on the demand for redistribution
and propose an alternative way to think about the
preferences of the median voter or, less stringently,
the preferences of middle-income voters. In so doing,
we assume that the preferences of middle-income vot-
ers are critical to the politics of redistribution and set
aside, for the time being, the question of how these
preferences are translated into policy. Our empirical
analysis explores the role of partisanship as an inter-
vening variable. However, our core argument, about
middle-income preferences, does not depend on stak-
ing a strong position in debates about whether parties
cater to core constituencies or the median voter.
Like a number of recent political-economy models,
most notably Iversen and Soskice (2006), our theo-
retical framework posits a society consisting of three
classes or social groups defined by income: the poor, the
middle, and the affluent. As long as no one class consti-
tutes a majority of the electorate, redistributive policy
will be set by a coalition of two groups, and such coali-
tions will almost certainly include the middle-income
group. These propositions are, of course, stylized sim-
plifications, but they capture core features of advanced
industrial societies and serve the useful purpose of fo-
cusing our attention on the question of whether middle-
income voters will ally with the poor or the affluent.
In the theoretical model proposed by Iversen and
Soskice (2006), the answer to this question depends
on the ability of parties to make credible commit-
ments under different electoral rules. Under majori-
tarian rules, middle-income voters will be inclined to
support center-right parties because they fear that
center-left parties will revert to the preferences of
the left’s poor constituency once in government. The
interests of middle-income voters are more closely
aligned with the first-order preferences of the afflu-
ent (no redistribution) than with those of the poor
(redistribution from the nonpoor to the poor). How-
ever, proportional representation provides for parties
that represent the middle-income group alone, making
possible the formation of center-left coalition govern-
ments committed to redistributing income from the
affluent to the benefit of the middle and the poor
alike. A crucial feature of the Iversen-Soskice model
is that the middle-income group never imposes (re-
distributive) taxes on itself. In contrast, the model
of redistribution that underlies our approach allows
for this possibility or, alternatively, for the possibil-
ity that the middle-income group will claim a less-
than-equal share of the redistributive benefits that the
poor and the middle jointly derive from taxing the
affluent.
The RMR model’s conception of short-term income
maximization as the foundation for preferences over
redistributive policy is surely too narrow. We can distin-
guish two broad alternatives to the RMR approach to
preferences. One alternative shares the RMR model’s
emphasis on material self-interest, but posits that in-
dividuals calculate the costs and benefits of redistri-
bution with a more extended time horizon, or in a
more “enlightened” manner. Insurance against future
income losses (Iversen and Soskice 2001; Moene and
Wallerstein 2001, 2003) or the recognition of negative
externalities associated with inequality (Alesina and
Giuliano 2009) might motivate affluent individuals to
support redistributive policies that do not benefit them
immediately. The other alternative holds that other-
regarding motivations of an altruistic nature also mat-
ter; in other words, individuals are (sometimes) willing
to forego some income for the benefit of others. Our
core argument builds on this latter approach, which
emphasizes that individuals should be viewed not as
2

psr1100012 xxx (xxx) April 25, 2011 14:49
American Political Science Review Vol. 105, No. 2
atomized maximizers of self-interest, however enlight-
ened, but as members of social groups or networks.
The notion of social affinity features prominently in
recent studies of how racial and ethnic fractionalization
affects demand for redistribution. Luttmer’s (2001) in-
fluential analysis of individual-level support for wel-
fare spending in the U.S. provides strong evidence of
what he refers to as racial group loyalty. According
to Luttmer’s analysis, individuals living in neighbor-
hoods with many welfare recipients are, on average,
less supportive of welfare spending. However, prox-
imity to white welfare recipients increases support for
welfare spending among white respondents, whereas
proximity to black welfare recipients increases support
for welfare spending among black respondents. Cru-
cially, Luttmer shows that racial group loyalty is just as
strong among high-income respondents as it is among
low-income respondents (see also Gilens 2000).
Building on Luttmer’s work, Alesina and Glaeser
(2004) demonstrate that social spending correlates with
various measures of ethnic, linguistic, and religious
fractionalization on a cross-national basis. Although
their measures of fractionalization fail to capture this,
Alesina and Glaeser’s theoretical discussion clearly
recognizes that the crucial issue is not fractionaliza-
tion per se, but rather how racial or ethnic cleavages
map onto the income distribution (cf. Selway 2011).
“Significant numbers of minorities among the poor,”
they argue, means that “the majority population can
be roused against transferring money to people who
are different from themselves” (Alesina and Glaeser
2004, 134).
More recently, Shayo’s (2009) important contribu-
tion suggests that the concept of social affinity might
be usefully extended to social classes defined by in-
come. Positing that social identities are defined by self-
categorization into groups and that there are multiple
groups with which any given individual might iden-
tify (see Turner et al. 1987), Shayo (2009) argues that
individuals choose to identify with one or another
groupsay, their class or their nationbased on (1)
perceived social distance to the prototypical member
of each group, and (2) the relative status of the group
in question. In our theoretical framework, individu-
als are enmeshed in social networks that are typically
class based, regardless of whether they identify with
their class. Members of the middle-income group must
decide whether they prefer an alliance with the poor
or with the affluent. Like Shayo, we posit that social
distance constitutes an important consideration in the
choice of alternative coalitions and suppose that in-
come differentials are a reasonably good proxy for so-
cial distance, at least in the absence of cross-cutting eth-
nic or racial cleavages.
3
It follows from these premises
that we should expect middle-income voters to be more
inclined to empathize with the poorand to support
3
Although Shayo (2009) formulates his theory in terms of individ-
uals’ perceptions of the social distance between themselves and the
prototype of a given group, he clearly believes, as we do, that such
perceptions correspond to objective group attributes to a significant
degree.
parties that advocate pro-poor redistributive policies
when the income distance to the poor is small relative
to the income distance to the affluent.
In our conceptualization, social affinity involves al-
truistic behavior, but it is quite different from general-
ized altruism. If middle-income voters were motivated
by generalized altruism, then their sympathy for the
poor would increase with the distance between their in-
come and that of the poor. In contrast, proximity is the
source of affinity in our theoretical framework. Social
affinity involves what Fowler and Kam (2007) refer to
as parochial altruism: altruism bounded by perceptions
of common group membership or shared experience
(see also Goette, Huffman, and Meier 2006). Middle-
income voters empathize with the poor (or affluent)
when they perceive the poor (or affluent) as living lives
similar to their own. In particular, we expect middle-
income voters to empathize with the poor (or affluent)
to the extent that they live in the same neighborhoods,
send their children to the same schools, and circulate
within the same social networks (McPherson, Smith-
Lovin, and Cook 2001). Having relatives who are poor
is also likely to be a source of social affinity with the
poor.
Arguably, mobility between income groups is an
important component of (or condition for) affinity
between income groups. A number of recent cross-
national studies indicate that relative income mobility
tends to decline with aggregate inequality (Aaberge
et al. 2002; Andrews and Leigh 2009; Blanden 2009).
The obvious reason is that income gains or losses of
a given size translate into larger movements across
the income distribution, up or down, when the income
distribution is more compressed. The probability of
moving between any two positions in the income distri-
bution (say, between the 20th and the 50th percentile)
is in part a function of the distance between the two
positions. When the distance between the poor and the
middle-income group is small, members of the middle-
income group face a greater probability of becoming
poor (or having children with low incomes), and this
will, we hypothesize, reinforce their affinity with the
poor. Conversely, prospects of upward mobility will re-
inforce middle-income affinity with the affluent when
the distance between the middle and the affluent is
small.
In future work, analyzing individual preferences for
redistribution, we hope to disentangle the effects of
social affinity and self-interest informed by mobility
prospects. However, we do not view social affinity
and self-interest as competing explanations of individ-
ual preferences for redistribution. Rather, we want to
emphasize the potential complementarities of other-
regarding and self-interested motivations. Social soli-
darity may become an operative behavioral norm when
individuals have some rational reason to suppose it
might serve their own interests over the long run (cf.
Converse 1964).
Our argument focuses on middle-income voters, but
the underlying logic ought to apply to the poor and
the affluent as well. When the distance to the mid-
dle is small, the poor should feel more affinity with
3

psr1100012 xxx (xxx) April 25, 2011 14:49
Inequality and Redistribution May 2011
the middle-income group and demand less redistribu-
tion. Similarly, the affluent should feel affinity with the
middle-income group, and perhaps be less resistant to
redistribution, when the distance between the middle
and the affluent is small.
Our social affinity hypothesis stands in sharp contrast
to the social rivalry hypothesis articulated by Corneo
and Gr
¨
uner (2002). These authors posit that middle-
income voters oppose redistribution because they fear
it will enable the poor to gain access to middle-class
neighborhoods and social networks, thereby under-
mining their own relative position in the status hi-
erarchy. By this logic, proximity to the poor should
underminerather than promotesupport for redis-
tribution among middle-income voters.
4
The status
dimension of Shayo’s (2009) theoretical model also
points in the direction of social rivalry as an impor-
tant factor behind individual preferences for redistri-
bution. There is no middle class in the model that Shayo
presents, but he briefly discusses such an extension
(fn. 17). With respect to the poor, Shayo argues that
redistribution improves their status, increasing their
propensity to identify with their social class rather than
their nation. Adding a middle class to his model, the im-
plication would seem to be that greater proximity to the
poor should reduce the value of being middle class, ren-
dering middle-class individuals more likely to identify
with the nation and less likely to support redistribution.
In this article, we test the social affinity hypothesis
against macro data and relate our core argument to
previous macrocomparative studies of the relationship
between inequality and redistribution. From a macro-
comparative perspective, our key claim is that the com-
bination of relatively small income differences in the
lower half of the distribution and relatively large in-
come differences in the upper half provides the most
favorable conditions for redistributive politics. Con-
versely, the combination of relatively large income
differences in the lower half of the distribution and
relatively small differences in the upper half under-
mines support for redistribution among pivotal middle-
income voters.
Like Kristov, Lindert, and McClelland (1992), we
estimate models of redistribution with separate mea-
sures of income differentials in the two halves of the
income distribution. We hypothesize that the 90–50
earnings ratio (i.e., the ratio of earnings in the 90th
percentile to earnings in the 50th percentile) will be
associated with more redistribution and that the 50–10
earnings ratio (i.e., the ratio of earnings in the 50th
4
Curiously, the empirical evidence Corneo and Gr
¨
uner (2002)
present in support of their social rivalry hypothesis appears instead
to support our social affinity hypothesis. Using survey data from
12 countries, Corneo and Gr
¨
uner divide respondents into income
quintiles and then estimate the effects of occupational prestige dif-
ferentials on attitudes toward redistribution. Their results show that
support for redistribution in any given quintile decreases with oc-
cupational prestige differentials relative to lower quintiles, and in-
creases with prestige differentials relative to higher quintiles. Consid-
ering occupational prestige as an additional source (and alternative
measure) of social distance, these results are entirely consistent with
our theoretical framework.
percentile to earnings in the 10th percentile) will be
associated with less redistribution. Our argument im-
plies that these measures of upper- and lower-half in-
equality matter jointly to middle-income support for
redistribution. Conceiving social affinity with the poor
as the inverse of social affinity with the affluent, we
imagine that middle-income voters compare income
distances in the two halves of the distribution in the
process of choosing coalition partners. An increase of
the 90–50 ratio will only have the predicted effect of
moving middle-income voters toward greater support
for redistribution insofar as it is not offset by a corre-
sponding increase of the 50–10 ratio. At the same time,
however, 90–50 and 50–10 ratios are closely correlated
across countries and over time. To address this prob-
lem, we estimate models with a measure of how the two
ratios are related to each other: the 90–50 ratio divided
by the 50–10 ratio. This measure, which we refer to
as skew, rises as dispersion in the upper half of the
earnings distribution increases relative to dispersion in
the lower half and takes on a value of 1 whenever the
90–50 and 50–10 ratios are the same. We expect skew
to be positively associated with redistribution.
5
Our approach draws on insights from recent research
on racial and ethnic group solidarity, and posits that so-
cial affinities are also based on income. We do not argue
that income is a more important basis of social affinity
than ethnicity. In our view, the relative importance of
different sources of social affinity is an open empirical
question. Relying on the stock of immigrants as the best
available proxy for the ethnic concentration of minori-
ties among the poor, our empirical analysis begins to
address this question, but our primary objective here
is to establish that income-based social affinity matters
to the politics of redistribution.
EMPIRICAL SETUP
Our main empirical analysis consists of a series of
models of redistribution (measured as the percentage
change in Gini coefficients brought about by taxes and
government transfers) and social spending (measured
in percent of gross domestic product [GDP]). Redis-
tribution is the theoretically relevant variable, but our
data on redistribution is limited and entails potential
complications. Estimating similar models with social
spending as the dependent variable provides an impor-
tant test of the robustness of our findings. In this sec-
tion, we introduce the variables included in our models
5
Collinearity precludes interacting 90–50 and 50–10 ratios, but an
interaction model would anyway be inappropriate as a test of our
theory, which does not stipulate that dispersion of the bottom half of
the distribution conditions the effect of increasing the dispersion of
the top half of the distribution, or vice versa. To our knowledge, only
two previous studies have explored separate effects of inequality in
the upper and lower halves of the distribution. Although Moene and
Wallerstein (2003) fail to find any significant difference between the
effects of low- and high-end inequality, Schwabish, Smeeding, and
Osberg (2006) report results that are quite different from ours (more
on this in what follows). Consistent with our theory, Corcoran and
Evans’ (2010) analysis of local spending on public education in the
U.S. finds that low-end inequality is associated with less spending,
whereas high-end inequality is associated with more.
4

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Explaining Social Policy Preferences: Evidence from the Great Recession

TL;DR: This paper found that the personal experience of economic hardship, particularly the loss of a job, had a major effect on increasing support for welfare spending, and this effect was appreciably larger among Republicans than among Democrats.
BookDOI

Mass politics in tough times : opinions, votes, and protest in the Great Recession

TL;DR: Bermeo and Bartels as discussed by the authors studied the dynamics of economic opinions during the Great Recession and found that people were more likely to support redistribution in the United Kingdom during the financial crisis.
Journal ArticleDOI

Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets. By Evelyne Huber and John D. Stephens. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001. 368p. $54.00 cloth, $18.00 paper.

TL;DR: This article studied the course of social welfare policy over the second half of the twentieth century in 16 nations and examined social insurance and service programs, major public expenditure and revenue aggregates, and an array of fine-grained indicators of state redistributive and safety net outcomes, from 1960 through 1994.
MonographDOI

Skills and inequality: partisan politics and the political economy of education reforms in Western welfare states

TL;DR: Skills and Inequality as discussed by the authors studies the political economy of education and training reforms from the perspective of comparative welfare state research, highlighting the striking similarities between established worlds of welfare capitalism and educational regimes.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The Impact of Group Membership on Cooperation and Norm Enforcement: Evidence Using Random Assignment to Real Social Groups

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigate whether the social aspect of organizations has an important benefit, fostering unselfish cooperation and norm enforcement within the group, but also whether there is a dark side, in the form of hostility between groups.
Journal ArticleDOI

Religion and Preferences for Social Insurance

TL;DR: The authors argued that individuals who are religious are more likely to prefer lower levels of social insurance than will those who are not religious, and they empirically test their predictions using individual-level data on religiosity, individual-specific data on social insurance preferences, and cross-country data on Social Spending outcomes.
Journal ArticleDOI

Beyond the Self: Social Identity, Altruism, and Political Participation

TL;DR: The authors used allocations in dictator games towards an anonymous recipient and two recipients identified only as a registered Democrat or a registered Republican to test whether altruism and social identification significantly increase political participation.
Book

Capitalism, Democracy, and Welfare

TL;DR: In this article, the authors build on institutionalist theory in both economics and political science to offer a general political economy framework for the study of welfare capitalism, based on the key idea that social protection in a modern economy, both inside and outside the state, can be understood as protection of specific investments in human capital.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (7)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "The structure of inequality and the politics of redistribution" ?

In addition, the authors present survey evidence on preferences for redistribution among middle-income voters that is consistent with their theory and regression results indicating that the left parties are more likely to participate in government when the structure of inequality is characterized by skew. 

One hypothesis to be explored in future work is that center-right parties adjust strategically to the advantages that center-left parties enjoy when the structure of inequality is skewed, pursuing more redistributive policies. Although the authors do not believe that governments are exclusively responsive to the policy preferences of middle-income voters, it seems reasonable to suppose that middle-income voters play a pivotal role in coalitional politics. Their preliminary analysis of survey data suggests that the structure of inequality shapes the preferences of middle-income voters and that these preferences in turn impact government policy. Further analysis of individual preferences constitutes an obvious next step that the authors intend to pursue. 

In several of these countries—notably, Australia, France, Ireland, and Switzerland—government policy appears to have become more redistributive relative to countries in which earnings skew has remained stable. 

As Piketty and Saez (2003) suggest, the rapid growth of corporate compensation, linked to the dynamics of equity markets, constitutes yet another possible factor behind changes in the structure of earnings inequality over the past two decades. 

With redistribution as the dependent variable, introducing government partisanship into their models does not noticeably alter the estimated effects of skew. 

A number of recent crossnational studies indicate that relative income mobility tends to decline with aggregate inequality (Aaberge et al. 

In particular, the authors expect middleincome voters to empathize with the poor (or affluent) to the extent that they live in the same neighborhoods, send their children to the same schools, and circulate within the same social networks (McPherson, SmithLovin, and Cook 2001).