scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Regulation and Investment

TLDR
In this paper, the authors used newly assembled data on regulation in several sectors of many OECD countries to provide evidence that regulatory reform of product markets is associated with an increase in investment.
Abstract
use newly assembled data on regulation in several sectors of many OECD countries to provide evidence that regulatory reform of product markets is associated with an increase in investment. A component of reform that plays a very important role is entry liberalization, but privatization also has a substantial effect on investment. Sensitivity analysis suggests that our results are robust. (JEL: E22, L5)

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
REGULATION AND INVESTMENT
Alberto Alesina
Silvia Ardagna
Giuseppe Nicoletti
Fabio Schiantarelli
Working Paper 9560
http://www.nber.org/papers/w9560
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
March 2003
We would like to thank Frank Gollop and participants at seminars at Boston College, Brandeis and IGIER
Bocconi for useful comments. Alesina is grateful for financial support to the NSF for a grant through the
NBER. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of
the institutions to which they are affiliated or the National Bureau of Economic Research.
©2003 by Alberto Alesina, Silvia Ardagna, Giuseppe Nicoletti, and Fabio Schiantarelli. All rights
reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission
provided that full credit including ©notice, is given to the source.

Regulation and Investment
Alberto Alesina, Silvia Ardagna, Giuseppe Nicoletti, and Fabio Schiantarelli
NBER Working Paper No. 9560
March 2003
JEL No. A1
ABSTRACT
One commonly held view about the difference between continental European countries and other
OECD economies, especially the United States, is that the heavy regulation of Europe reduces its
growth. Using newly assembled data on regulation in several sectors of many OECD countries, we
provide substantial and robust evidence that various measures of regulation in the product market,
concerning in particular entry barriers, are negatively related to investment. The implications of our
analysis are clear: regulatory reforms, especially those that liberalize entry, are very likely to spur
investment.
Alberto Alesina Silvia Ardagna
Department of Economics Wellesley College
Harvard University
Cambridge, MA 02138
and NBER
aalesina@harvard.edu
Giuseppe Nicoletti Fabio Schiantarelli
OECD Boston College

Re gulation and Investment
Alberto Alesina, Silvia Ardagna, Giuseppe Nicoletti, and Fabio Schiantarelli
(Harv ard University, Wellesle y College, OECD, and Boston College)
December 2002
Re vised February 2003
Abstract
One commonly held view about the difference between continental Eu-
ropean countries and other OECD economies, especially the United States,
is that the heavy regulation of Europe reduces its growth. Using newly as-
sembled data on regulation in several sectors of many OECD countries, we
provide substantial and robust evidence that various measures of regulation
in the product market, concerning in particular entry barriers, are negatively
related to investment. The implications of our analysis are clear: regulatory
reforms, especially those that liberalize entry, are very likely to spur invest-
ment.
1 Intr o duction
In the past decade the rate of GDP growth has been remarkably different amongst
OECD countries. One of the most striking and often cited comparison is the one
between the US with a 4.3 percent average GDP growth in the second half of the
nineties and large continental European economies (Germany, Italy and France)
with 2 percent average growth. One commonly held explanation of these differ-
ences is that a stricter regulation of markets has pre vented faster growth in many
European countries especially in a period, the nineties, of rapid technological in-
novation. Is this true? This paper suggests that the answer is “yes”: various mea-
sures of product market regulation are negatively related to investment, which is,
of course, an important engine of growth.
We would like to thank Frank Gollop and participants at seminars at Boston College, Brandeis
and IGIER Bocconi for useful comments. Alesina is grateful for Þnancial support to the NSF for
a grant through the NBER. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and do not
necessarily represent those of the institutions to which they are afÞliated.
1

In the last decade or so, most OECD countries have experienced some form of
regulatory reforms (deregulation for short) implying entry liberalization and pri-
vatization. However, the timing, extent, nature, and starting point varies across
countries. For instance, the United States started deregulating earlier, already in
the seventies. In 1977, 17 per cent of the US GNP was produced by fully regulated
industries, and by 1988 this total had been cut to 6.6 percent of GNP.
1
Other early
and decisive reformers have been New Zealand and Britain, while laggards have
been Italy and France.
We rely on these diverse histories to study the effects of regulatory reforms
in sectors which were traditionally most heavily sheltered from competition and
have witnessed, at different times and to different degrees, some form of dereg-
ulation and privatization in various countries. SpeciÞcally, we look at the ef fe cts
of regulation on investment in the transport (airlines, road freight and railways),
communication (telecommunications and postal) and utilities (electricity and gas)
sectors. We measure regulation with different time varying indicators that capture
entry barriers and the extent of public ownership, among other things.
We Þnd that regulatory reforms have had a signiÞcant positive impact on capital
accumulation in the transport, communication, and utilities industries. In particu-
lar, liberalization of entry in potentially competitive markets seems to have had
the largest and most signiÞcant impact on private investment.
2
The effect of pri-
vatization is less clear-cut. On the one hand privatization may lead to more proÞt
opportunities for private Þrms; on the other hand public enterprises may overinvest
if they pursue political objectives and/or if managers are not constrained by the dis-
cipline imposed by capital markets. There is also evidence that the marginal effect
of deregulation on investment is greater when the policy reform is large and when
changes occur starting from already low er levels of regulation. In other words,
small changes in a heavy regulated environment are not likely to produce much of
an effect.
Much of the literature on the effects of regulation in OECD countries is con-
cerned with the labor market, see for instance, Blanchard and Wolfers (2000).
Work on the macroeconomic effects of goods market is more limited.
3
Blanchard
and Giavazzi (2001) develop an insightful model of both labor market and product
1
See Winston (1993). The Þgures are from the January 1991 Survey of Current Business.
2
Our conclusion that less intrusive government intervention favors private investment is consistent
with the Þnding by Alesina et al. (2002). They show in a panel of OECD countrie s that a reduction of
the size of government measured by total spending over GDP and total taxation increases the private
accumulation of capital. Results by Blanchard and Perotti (2002) speciÞcallyontheUSareonthe
same line.
3
There is of course a vast literature on the microeconomics of regulation and deregulation. See
for instance the survey by Joskow and Rose (1989) and Winston (1993).
2

market regulation and their interconnection. Nicoletti et al. (2001a, b) provide
empirical evidence in favor of a negative effect of anti-competitiv e product market
regulation on employment in a panel of OECD countries. Moreover, Nicoletti and
Scarpetta (2002) Þnd that product market regulation lowers multifactor productiv-
ity growth in O ECD countries, while Bassanini and Ernst (2002) Þnd a negative
effect of regulation on R&D. Finally, Djankov, La Porta, Lopez de Silanes, and
Shleifer (2002) focus on regulations that affect how easy it is to start a business in
85 countries. Their paper contrasts developing countries with developed ones and
lends support to the view of excessive regul ation as a hindrance to entrepreneur-
ship.
4
To our knowledge, there are no contributions in the literature that use broad
time varying measures of product market regulation and look at the relationship
between regulatory reforms and investment in a panel context.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a simple model to il-
lustrate the channels through which regulation can affect capital accumulation.
Section 3 describes our data and, in particular , the measurement of the regulatory
environment. Section 4 discusses our results in sectors (utilities, telecommunica-
tion, transport) which were heavily regulated and have experienced various forms
of deregulation. The last section concludes.
2 Product Market Regulation and Investment: Some The-
ory
Product market regulation can inßuence investment in several ways. First, as Blan-
chard and Giavazzi (2001) emphasize in a non-competitive model of employment
determination, changes in regulation affect the markup of prices over marginal
costs, because of their impact, for instance, on entry barriers and, hence, on the
number of Þrms. Second, regulation can inßuence the costs that even existing
Þrms face when expanding their productive capacity. For example, red tape and
other forms of regulatory burdens can increase Þrms’ costs of adjusting the capital
stock and hamper their capacity to react to changes in fundamentals. Third, for cer-
tain sectors, regulation imposes a ceiling on the rate of return on capital that Þrms
are allowed to earn; this affects the demand for capital relative to labor (Averch
and Johnson (1962)). Finally, if product markets regulatory reforms occur together
with pri vatization (or nationalization) policies, changes in ownership structure can
also affect investment.
4
A related literature asks the question whether competition stimulates Þrms’ productivity. See,
for instance, Nickell (1996) who shows that both the level and growth rates of Þrms’ productivity are
positively affected by measures of competition. This suggests that regulatory reforms should have
positive productivity effects, insofar as they succeed in stimulating competition.
3

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Innovation and competitive pressure

TL;DR: In this paper, the effects of competition on process and product innovation were analyzed for a variety of market structures, including markets with restricted or free entry and markets characterized by either price or quantity competition.
Report SeriesDOI

Product Market Regulation in the Non-Manufacturing Sectors of OECD Countries

TL;DR: In this article, a new set of indicators that measure differences in the regulation of non-manufacturing sectors of OECD countries over the past three decades is presented. But the indicators focus on regulations that affect competitive pressures in areas where competition is economically viable and on the potential costs that these regulations entail for economic activities that use the output of regulated sectors as intermediate inputs in production.
Journal ArticleDOI

Electricity Market Reform in the European Union: Review of Progress toward Liberalization & Integration*

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors review the progress towards a single European electricity market and discuss the emerging issues of market concentration, investments, and security of supply as well as some aspects of market design and regulation.
Report SeriesDOI

Product Market Regulation in OECD Countries

TL;DR: In this article, the authors describe trends in product market regulation in OECD countries over the period 1998 to 2003 and find that regulatory impediments to competition have declined in all OECD countries in recent years.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Effect of Corporate Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present new data on effective corporate income tax rates in 85 countries in 2004 and show that corporate tax rates are correlated with investment in manufacturing but not services, as well as with the size of the informal economy.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations.

TL;DR: In this article, the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator optimally exploits all the linear moment restrictions that follow from the assumption of no serial correlation in the errors, in an equation which contains individual effects, lagged dependent variables and no strictly exogenous variables.
Journal ArticleDOI

Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects

Stephen Nickell
- 01 Nov 1981 - 
Journal ArticleDOI

Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examined bias in dynamic models with fixed effects where both the number of time series observations and cross-sectional replications are small, and the formula bias estimate was in line with that in published Monte Carlo studies.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Regulation of Entry

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present new data on the regulation of entry of start-up firms in 85 countries, covering the number of procedures, official time, and official cost that a startup must bear before it can operate legally.
Journal ArticleDOI

Competition and corporate performance

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present evidence that competition, as measured by increased numbers of competitors or by lower levels of rents, is associated with a significantly higher rate of total factor productivity growth.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Regulation and investment" ?

Using newly assembled data on regulation in several sectors of many OECD countries, the authors provide substantial and robust evidence that various measures of regulation in the product market, concerning in particular entry barriers, are negatively related to investment. 

The general conclusion that can be derived from the models the authors have analyzed so far is that deregulation of product markets has a positive effect on capital accumulation if it generates a reduction in the markup of prices over marginal costs (for instance through a reduction in entry barriers) or if it lowers costs of adjusting the capital stock. 

In response to a regulatory reform that decreases the cost of adjusting the capital stock, the shadow value of capital initially jumps up and then it settles to a lower steady state value. 

Aspects of deregulation that remove binding constraints on rates of return or imply privatization of public or semi-public enterprises may determine a reduction of investment. 

The disappearing or reduced importance of a dominant publicly owned player, facing a soft budget constraint, is one of the reasons why deregulation has lead to a decrease in entry barriers for new privately owned Þrms. 

Managers of public enterprises often behave as empire builders, because their reward in terms of monetary compensation, power, and perks may be related to the size of the organization. 

Deregulation has also been particularly strong in the UK and New Zealand, which were highly regulated at the beginning of the sample, while they rank among the most market-oriented economies in 1998. 

In 1977, 17 per cent of the US GNP was produced by fully regulated industries, and by 1988 this total had been cut to 6.6 percent of GNP.1 

Their model predicts an increase in the investment rate in the long-run of 3.27 percentage points (from 4.96% to 8.23%) using the coefÞcients of Model 2 Panel A. 

The authors can easily model increasing returns following Rotemberg and Woodford (1995) by using the production function F(Ki , Li ) − # with F(Ki , Li ) displaying constant returns, and # representing a positive constant determined by technology only and capturing Þxed costs. 

For compactness, the authors report the sum of the coefÞcients of the regulation variable (Sum) and a test for its equality to zero, which is the most relevant test to assess the longrun effect of regulation on investment. 

The data for sectors that have experienced signiÞcant changes in the regulatory environment suggest that deregulation leads to greater investment in the long-run. 

The sum of the coefÞcients on the value added to capital terms (Sum2) 18The correlation between their summary measure of regulation REGOL and the union density and the replacement rate variables is equal 0.18; the correlation between REGOL and the employment protection index is 0.68, while the correlation between REGOL and the remaining indices measuring regulation in labor markets is around 0.4.